INFORMATION SHARING DEVICES IN ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY: THE EU ECO-LABEL AND EMAS
Keith Brouhle
September 26, 2000
While society has always been faced with environmental problems, the method
in which public policy has tried to address these problems has evolved over
time. The beginning of significant environmental legislation can be traced to
the command and control policies of the late 1960s and 1970s. This
method of regulating the environment relied on product bans and the setting
of emissions standards. At a time when dangerous products like DDT were rampant,
command and control policies were a useful first step in cleaning up the environment.
The policies, however, were reactive and gave no incentive for firms to reduce
their pollution beyond the mandated levels. Furthermore, the mandated restrictions
on production were extremely inflexible and not cost effective.
In a move toward recognizing the power of the market to correct environmental
problems, environmental policies in the late 1980s and 1990s focused
on the use of economic instruments. Environmental taxes and later tradable permits
attempt to address the externalities associated with environmental problems
by correcting market prices. Once prices are correctly raised or lowered, proper
signals are given to producers and consumers, and the market will function more
efficiently. Information asymmetries, however, can often prevent an efficient
market outcome. Often times, for example, firms have more information than the
government in terms of their costs of abatement. On the other side of the market,
the government does not know, but can only estimate, the true benefits of pollution
reduction to consumers. Without having either piece of information, the government
has difficulty setting the correct tax or number of permits. Hence, economic
instruments, while efficient in theory, can fail to reach this outcome in practice
due to a lack of information.
A new policy tool of voluntary agreements has become more popular in the past
five to ten years mainly as a way to address these information asymmetries.
Since the government does not have all the necessary information to create policies
to ameliorate environmental problems, voluntary agreements reach out to firms
and consumers to share this information. A voluntary agreement involves representatives
of government and industry entering into an agreement to reduce the environmental
impact of industrial activity. Since government cannot regulate every type of
economic activity of a firm, even though all economic activity has some impact
on the environment, voluntary agreements can extend the scope of environmental
protection. Thus, voluntary agreements have found a role in supplementing the
use of economic instruments. Besides their advantage in overcoming information
deficiencies, voluntary agreements tend to be proactive measures that address
pollution before its starts and does so at a low cost due to their flexible,
voluntary nature. Of course, voluntary agreements are often criticized as being
weak and nothing more than business as usual. Furthermore, there is often concern
of a free-rider problem: industries can promise to reduce pollution but firms
may have the incentive to free-ride off the pollution reduction
of other firms in the industry.
In this paper, I will focus on two voluntary agreements in the European Union,
the EU eco-label and Eco-Management and Audit Scheme (EMAS). These voluntary
agreements are interesting as they both attempt to facilitate the exchange of
information between producers and consumers. The premise of the programs is
that the parties, once informed, will use the information to make decisions
that will improve the environment. Thus, there are two key steps. First, the
voluntary agreements focus on the provision of information. Second, but equally
important, the programs rely on the ability of the agents to use the information.
Section two introduces the important role that information plays in a market
economy. While both producers and consumers are integral in determining the
market outcome, the two programs are geared toward different parties. The EU
eco-label focuses on consumers as the impetus that will lead to change while
the EMAS program places attention on producers. Sections three and four, then,
discuss the information provisions of the EU eco-label and EMAS programs. Section
five concludes with lessons to be learned from the two programs.
Section 2: Information and the Market
The efficiency of competitive markets is a well-established tenet of neo-classical
economic theory. A key assumption that the efficiency result rests upon is that
agents have perfect information (one implication of which is that knowledge
about a products characteristics is equally distributed between buyers
and sellers). While economists have realized that this assumption of perfect
information is never attainable, the obstacles to acquiring information have
only recently been more fully developed and explored. There exist explicit costs
in acquiring information (search costs) as well as implicit costs in making
use of information (adverse selection, moral hazard). These costs restrict the
flow of information, and the much heralded efficiency result of the neoclassical
model can break down.
George Akerlof presented a classic example of how this information asymmetry
can affect the functioning of a market in his 1970 article The Market
for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism. Looking at the
used car market, he noted that the market is characterized by asymmetric information
as sellers know the true quality of their car, but buyers can only make inferences
about the quality level. When buyers know only the average car quality and are
unable to obtain further information, they will only pay an amount that the
average quality car is worth. High quality car owners, however, will not accept
such a payment since their cars are worth more (low quality car owners, of course,
are happy to be getting a premium on their cars). Buyers, however, will realize
that only low quality cars will be left on the market and accordingly revise
their willingness to pay. This downward spiral continues until only the low
quality cars are left for sale. In a similar spirit, one can apply this analysis
to the market for environmentally friendly products. While some firms may claim
to produce high quality (green) goods, consumers are unable to verify
if this is really the case. The information uncertainty, then, leads consumers
to revise their expectations downward, and this causes the market to only provide
low quality (dirty) products because consumers cannot successfully
evaluate product characteristics.
The fact that used car markets for all quality cars exist, however, indicates
that it is possible to overcome these information asymmetries. In the used car
market, information is provided through several mechanisms. For example, buyers
may consult guides like Consumer Reports to gain information about
the average quality of a certain car brand. Furthermore, an expert mechanic
can provide some information about the specific car in question. Sellers, too,
attempt to provide information to help the market operate. For example, sellers
may take their cars to a dealership that can establish a reputation for honesty.
Also, the existence and type of a warranty provides a signal to consumers about
the quality of the car according to the seller. The mechanism of exchanging
information is successful because cars can be classified as an experience good.
With such a good, the quality of the good can be ascertained but only after
use of the good. All the agents above, the car mechanic, Consumer Reports,
or the used car salesman, rely on their experience of the good (or similar types
of good; i.e. the same make/model car) to convey information.
The exchange of information about the environmental attributes of a good, however,
is different than the exchange of information about the attributes of a car.
The difference arises because a green product is not an experience
good but a credence good: a good whose quality cannot be ascertained even after
use of the good. For example, consumers are not present at the time of production
to determine the true cleanliness of the production method. Consumers
also cannot ascertain the environmental quality of a good like the percentage
of recycled content at reasonable costs. Thus, even after people use the good,
they are in no better position to evaluate its quality. It is impossible, then,
for any of the above mechanisms (ex. repeat purchases, reputation effects) to
transmit information, and the existence of the market is called into doubt.
Since the market cannot provide information, this may posit a role for government
to play. The EU eco-label and Eco-Management and Audit Scheme (EMAS) are voluntary
programs that attempt to overcome the inefficiencies of the market by promoting
the exchange of trustworthy, reliable information. First, the two programs are
voluntary as they do not proscribe specific tasks for a firm to undertake to
become clean; rather, both programs encourage self-regulation as firms can decide
which steps to undertake to reduce the environmental impact of their activities.
Second, the programs facilitate the exchange of information concerning the activities
of firms to become clean. That is, information held by the firm on the level
of environmental damage caused in the production and use of the good is transmitted
to consumers. The underlying premises of both programs is that information given
to consumers will help guide their purchasing decisions to favor products more
in line with their preferences. And if agents have green preferences,
the greater consumer demand for these products will then induce companies to
improve their products and/or production methods. The advantage of this type
of policy compared to other types of environmental policy is that it requires
only the smallest intrusion by government. The government does not tell firms
what to produce or how to produce a product, they do not have to estimate marginal
abatement or benefit curves to determine an optimal tax, they simply aid in
the exchange of information to consumers. If the government provision of information
is credible, consistent, and comparable, then consumers will be more likely
to use the information which will push the market work toward a more socially
desirable outcome.
The ability of the information exchange to lead to an efficient market outcome,
however, depends not only on the provision of credible, consistent, and comparable
information, but also on the willingness of consumers to use this information.
Depending on the type of benefits that consuming a good yields, information
provided by the government has different effects on consumer behavior. For example,
when a person consumes the services of a car, the benefits they receive (the
ease and convenience of getting from point A to point B) are private. They accrue
only to the person who uses the car and are not received by the population in
general. The sum of the benefits, then, determines how much money the individual
is willing to pay for the product. The benefits of consuming an environmentally
friendly good, on the other hand, may yield private and public benefits. When
one buys a green good, they personally value the reduced pollution
to the environment. The reduced pollution, however, yields a stream of benefits
enjoyed by others too. That is, the reduced pollution is a public good as anyone
can enjoy it while not reducing the availability of the good to others. As in
the case of the car, the willingness to pay for the green good will
be a reflection of the (private) benefits the individual receives, and thus,
there is a difference between how much they are willing to pay and the total
value that the good yields due to the existence of the public benefits. The
greater the degree of public benefits that the good yields, the greater is the
divergence. This results in a non-optimal amount of the good being purchased
and has important implications for the EU eco-label and EMAS programs.
Section 3: EU Eco-label
Section 3.1: The EU eco-label regulation
Responding to the sustainability movement started at the UN Conference on Environment
and Development (Rio Conference), the EU introduced the eco-label scheme in
early 1992. Since firms have the option of qualifying their products for the
eco-label or not, the EU eco-label scheme can be considered a voluntary agreement.
The regulation has two main parts:
(1) providing consumers with better information on the environmental impact
of products;
(2) promoting the design, production, marketing and use of products which have
a reduced environmental impact during their entire life cycle
(Council Regulation 880/92)
The first part of the regulation, providing consumers with information about
the environmental impact of products, illustrates the reliance the program places
on consumers. The reduced environmental impact of the good is transmitted though
a logo of a daisy (see figure 1) that firms are allowed to use on their products,
packaging, and/or advertisements if they meet the standards of the eco-label.
If consumers are environmentally conscious and value a cleaner environment,
they will exercise their preferences by buying eco-labeled products. The success
of the program in reducing the economic impact on the environment is dependent
upon the strength of this green consumer demand.
The second aspect of the regulation deals with the eco-labeled products themselves.
Interestingly, the definition of products that have a reduced environmental
impact is not given in the regulation; rather, the regulation calls for
a regulatory committee to develop standards for individual product groups. The
regulatory committee involves all relevant parties, including DG Environment,
the EU Commission, industry trade groups, NGOs, and private citizens.
The criteria that have developed out of these regulatory committees are unique
in three respects. First, as the regulation states, the analysis is conducted
on the entire life cycle of a product. Such a cradle-to-grave approach
includes the extraction of raw materials, the production and distribution of
the product, the actual use of the product, and finally, the disposal of the
product. The second unique aspect of the criteria development is that it establishes
an absolute quality level. The cleanest producers in a given product category
do not de facto earn the eco-label; they must qualify by meeting an absolute
standard of cleanliness. The third aspect of the criteria development
that deserves mention is the type of label that is given. The effect of each
activity on the environment at each stage in the life cycle is given a score,
scores are then weighted and added together to get a final number that determines
if the product qualifies for the label. This type of label, a Type I label by
ISO standards, does not provide detailed information about specific attributes.
Nutrition labeling, on the other hand, falls into the category of Type III labels
as they provide detailed information about specific product attributes. The
value of a Type I versus Type III label has been greatly debated. Some argue
that the increased information of a Type III label allows consumers to make
better decisions while other claim the increased information can lead to consumer
confusion.
Section 3.2: Evaluation of the EU eco-label
The EU eco-label has had a slow and tenuous start. While it now has over 200
products registered in the program , there was only one product that qualified
for the label in the first three years. The number of products has increased
steadily since Hoover received the first label, but it has still not reached
that critical mass where consumers are familiar with the label and consumers
demand products with an eco-label. Suppliers cite a lack of consumer demand
as the main reason why they have not produced goods to qualify for the eco-label.
Consumers, however, say they are unable to exercise their demand for green
goods because of a lack of products on the market. Thus, it appears that the
EU eco-label is stuck in a vicious cycle: few green products are
produced due to a lack of demand while the relative absence of green
goods on the market does not allow consumers to show their demand. The disappointing
results of the program to date can largely be traced to the informational requirements
of the program. At the same time, consumers have not had enough information
about the EU eco-label and too much information from other labels and logos.
Each of these problems will be discussed below.
Section 3.2.1: Not enough information
Consumer awareness of the EU eco-label program is exceedingly small. The low
level of awareness is caused by two factors: a lack of advertising of the program
and a lack of consumer contact with goods that have the eco-label. There has
been a lack of funding to advertise the program at both the EU and national
level. The EU set up the eco-label program but set aside a small amount of money
to run the program. The low level of expenditures has not allowed mass-media
type advertisements (TV, newspaper ads) to explain the workings of the program.
The main method of advertising at the EU level has been participation in trade
shows and the diffusion of brochures to interested parties.
The EU hoped that national governments would encourage and promote the EU eco-label
scheme. This was a naive hope given the fact that the EU created an eco-label
that would compete with national eco-labels. Most national eco-labels receive
funding from their home government and also rely on a surcharge on products
sold displaying the eco-label. Greater success of the EU eco-label, then, could
come at the expense of national eco-labeled products. If consumers switch from
national eco-labeled products to products with the EU eco-label, the decline
in sales of products in national eco-labeled programs would create a funding
shortfall in the programs and greater pressure for money from the national government.
In addition, the prestige of national eco-labeled schemes means that national
governments are not rushing to the opportunity to fund the EU eco-label (Eiderstrom,
1998, 197).
A second reason for the low level of consumer awareness of the eco-label program
is that there are not enough eco-labeled products on the market. The EU has
only set up criteria for fifteen product groups, many of which are product groups
that consumers rarely shop for (ex. washing machines, refrigerators, computers).
In addition, the two hundred plus products is a rather small number when one
considers the entire range of goods that consumers face. As a point of comparison,
the German Blue Angel eco-label has around 4,000 registered products (http://www.blauer-engel.de/).
The result of the having such a small number of products registered in the program
is that consumers do not come into contact with EU eco-labeled products in their
everyday shopping. In fact, an informal survey in at least two supermarkets
in five EU countries failed to turn up a single eco-labeled product in the more
commonly used products groups of detergents (laundry and dishwashing) and paper
products (toilet paper and paper towels). Even if one runs into a product that
has been awarded the EU eco-label, it is unlikely that they know what the logo
stands for. OVIO, a Belgium think tank, carried out a study on consumer recognition
of the EU eco-label in two supermarket chains.
A total of 373 customers were presented ten logos that could be found
on products in their stores. They were [asked] which of them they recognized
and [the] meaning they attributed to them. 16.1% thought they had seen the EU
eco-label before. But when asked for the meaning of it, only 11.5% of those
16.1% (actually 1.85% of all respondents) gave a good explanation.
(Pots, Senesael, DeClercq, 1998, 97)
Thus, a lack of knowledge about the EU eco-label program, caused by a lack of
advertising of the program and a lack of consumer contact with eco-labeled products,
is the first obstacle to a successful program.
Section 3.2.2: Too much info
While the consumer lacks information about the EU eco-label program, they are
at the same time bombarded by too much information from other logos and brands.
The information overload does not help consumers make purchasing decisions which
more closely reflect their preferences; rather, the information overload causes
consumers to be confused and suspicious of green claims. The EU contributes
to the information overload itself through the EU energy label, a mandatory
labeling program of the energy consumption of household appliances. Also adding
to the problem are the national or regional eco-labeling schemes. The most popular
and widespread is the Blue Angel program in Germany. Started in
1977, it is estimated that 75% of German customers prefer to buy products carrying
the label (Business Europe, May 15, 1995). The next largest eco-label scheme
is the Nordic Swan program supported by the Scandinavian countries of Norway,
Sweden, Iceland and Finland. Many other national and regional labeling schemes
exist; in fact, the EU eco-label now co-exists with eight major schemes (the
German Blue Angel, the Nordic Swan, the Swedish Good Environmental Choice, the
Dutch Milieukeur, the French NF-Environment, the Spanish Medio Ambiente, the
Catalan Medi Ambient, and the Austrian UmweltZeichen) (http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/ecolabel/proprev.htm).
In addition to the sheer number of eco-labeling schemes, the relationship between
the EU eco-label and national eco-labeling schemes can also lead to confusion.
This is because a product that qualifies for a national eco-label may not qualify
for the EU eco-label or vice-versa due to different criteria requirements for
each program.
Probably the largest source of information that contributes to consumer confusion
comes from private logos and claims. Firms often label products as environmentally
friendly or provide some type of logo or claim to invoke environmental responsibility.
The claims tend to be unverifiable and often misleading. What does it mean to
be environmentally friendly or environmentally safe
and how does one verify this? Even verifiable environmental claims can be harmful
as they are often misleading. For example, a common green claim is that a product
is free of some harmful substance, like an aerosol can that is CFC-free.
While this is indeed true, it is questionable how the consumer benefits from
this information as CFCs were prohibited a number of years ago in European countries
so that all aerosol cans are now free of CFCs. Another area of claims that is
misleading to consumers is the use of vague words or phrases like recycled
or recyclable. In a survey by Morris, Hastak, and Mazis, only
five percent of respondents exhibited a thorough understanding of recycled
and recyclable consistent with EPA and FTC definitions (1995,
328). Because private claims are often vague, unverifiable or misleading, they
present the consumer with no real information. In fact, consumers have become
skeptical of the validity of private green claims and therefore tend to buy
fewer green products. The extraneous flow of information, then, debases all
environmental logos and labels, including the EU eco-label. Rather than improving
the efficiency of markets, this type of information can be worse than a complete
lack of information.
Section 3.3: The future of the eco-label
In order to improve the workings of the EU eco-label program, one needs to simultaneously
increase the level of awareness of the EU eco-label program and limit the extraneous
information that acts to confuse consumers. I will first evaluate the new provisions
of the EU eco-label revision document and then add some further suggestions
to encourage the success of the EU eco-label.
Section 3.3.1: The EU revision
Due to recognition that the EU eco-label was not performing as well as initially
hoped, the regulation has undergone a revision. The Commission presented the
new regulation in March of 1997, but due to the slow pace of legislation in
the EU, it has not yet been passed. It currently sits before the Parliament
for a second reading. While the new regulation is rather long, the main objectives
of the revision can be summarized as follows :
- to introduce a grading of the eco-label and define what information for consumers
has to be included in the label
- to introduce a ceiling for the annual fee to be charged for the use of the
label and a reduced rate of fee for SMEs and manufacturers of developing countries
- to ensure complementarity between the Community scheme and other major eco-label
schemes in the EU
- to encourage the diffusion of information about the program
(http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/ecolabel/proprev.htm)
The introduction of a grading of the eco-label or a more graduated type label
is an interesting proposal. The graduated label aims at providing more information
to consumers by providing information about product quality in specific attribute
areas. Thus, in addition to the daisy logo that certifies a product qualifies
for the eco-label, major attribute areas will be scored to tell the consumer
how clean the product is in each attribute area (see figure 2). In essence,
the graduated label incorporates characteristics of both a Type I and Type III
label. While the increased level of information can potentially be beneficial
as consumers could buy products that more closely reflect their preferences,
this must be weighted against the cost of processing the information and potentially
creating confusion.
The appropriate type of label, I believe, revolves to a great extent on if the
benefits are private or public. If the benefits are mostly private, individuals
have a greater incentive to care about specific product attributes (for example,
in the case of nutrition labeling, some individuals may look more closely at
saturated fat while others care about the caloric content due to their individual
health characteristics and the private benefit that they receive from consuming
the good). If the benefits are mostly public, however, you are buying the good
because it has a reduced environmental impact overall and you probably do not
need all the information of a Type III label . Unfortunately, the distinction
between private and public benefits does not yield a clear policy proscription
in regard to the EU eco-label program as the products often offer both private
and public benefits. The life cycle approach of the eco-label looks at all stages
of a product, most of which (including the extraction of inputs, production,
distribution, and disposal of the product) yield public benefits. However, eco-labeled
products can also have reduced environmental impact during use, and therefore,
the product yields private benefits too. For example, eco-labels have been given
to paints with lower levels of toxic fumes during application and washing machines
that use less energy and water. Since the benefits of buying an eco-labeled
product are both private and public, there does not exist overwhelming evidence
to support either a Type I or Type III label. For the simple fact that the EU
eco-label symbol of a daisy is not yet widely recognized, I think the introduction
of a graduated label has the potential to confuse consumers and is probably
premature at this time.
The second proposed change of limiting the fees for the eco-label is an encouraging
step. One goal of the revision should be to increase consumer contact with eco-labeled
products, and reducing the fee payment has the potential to encourage participation
from firms that may have been otherwise hesitant to join. The introduction of
a reduced fee schedule for SMEs (small and medium size enterprises) attempts
to target assistance to firms which need it most. Research has shown that SMEs
are less likely to join the eco-label program for several reasons. Their small
size means that they are less likely to have the personnel like a dedicated
environmental manager who would lead the push for the EU eco-label. Another
obstacle related to the smaller size of SMEs is the lower level of sales in
which to spread out the costs of qualifying for the eco-label. A reduced fee
schedule for SMEs and a general limit of the total fees for all firms are positive
steps to encourage more firms to produce eco-labeled goods.
The final two other major changes of the revision are steps in the right direction
but lack strength to be effective. For example, Article 10 of the revision document,
which deals with the promotion of the EU eco-label, states that Member
States and the EEO shall accompany the development of the scheme by promoting
awareness raising actions and information campaigns for consumers, producers,
retailers and the general public, specifically aimed at promoting the use of
the Community eco-label. There is no specific funding requirement or punishment
mechanism if the parties fail in this regard. Article 11, which deals with other
eco-labeled schemes, is equally vague. It states that
existing and new public and private eco-label schemes in the Member States shall
be organized in such a way as to apply to product groups for which no specific
Community eco-label criteria are established, ensuring complementarity between
such schemes and the Community eco-label. (Also), the Commission shall encourage
collaboration between the Community Scheme and schemes in the Member States
in order to ensure the necessary coordination.
(http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/ecolabel/proprev.htm)
In short, the revision allows national eco-labeling programs to continue to
operate and only asks for collaboration between programs. Increased
collaboration and increased information diffusion are steps in the right direction,
but it is difficult to see how the vague statements in the revision document
will be enough to ensure success.
Section 3.3.2: Recommendations
The revision document contains some potentially beneficial changes. More bold
and significant steps, however, should be taken to ensure the programs success.
One of the most important goals of the revision should be to increase the level
of understanding and knowledge of the program. The easiest way to accomplish
this is to expend some resources on advertising. Numerous studies have shown
that consumers are willing to spend more money for goods with a smaller impact
on the environment and that labeling can make significant changes in consumer
behavior . In order to capture this demand, it is necessary to expend some initial
resources educating the population about the existence and workings of the program.
Another way to increase the level of awareness of the program is to increase
the number of eco-labeled products. While the decision to qualify for the eco-label
is obviously in the hands of private firms, the European Union can take steps
to encourage more firms to participate. This does not mean that the standards
should be weakened to make it easier to qualify; rather, the cost of complying
with the program can be lowered. The revision suggestion of reducing fees for
SMEs is a positive step in this direction. A bolder step would be to reduce
the VAT on eco-labeled products. As the EU will have to spend money on the demand
side by educating consumers, it should initially expend similar resources on
the supply side to encourage firms to produce eco-labeled goods.
Finally, awareness of the EU eco-label program should be encouraged through
retail outlets. While again in private hands, the EU bureaucracy can work more
closely with retailers to promote the eco-label. Eco-labeled products offer
retailers an additional way to differentiate themselves from other retailers.
While price and service differentiation have been emphasized in the past, it
is possible that the increased consumer environmental movement offers retailers
a marketing tool. From the EU perspective, this focus on retailers will help
reach consumers for two reasons. First, retailers determine which products consumers
will be able to choose from, and second, it is easier to reach hundreds of retailers
than millions of consumers.
In addition to increasing awareness of the EU eco-label program, the second
major task to encourage the programs success is to limit the flow of extraneous
information. The excessive information confuses consumers and prevents the market
from operating efficiently. Again, the revision makes a step in this direction
by trying to ensure the complementarity between the EU eco-label and other national
eco-labeling programs. A stronger step will be to phase out national eco-labeling
programs. While countries with successful eco-labeling programs will be against
this proposal, this is a necessary step if the EU eco-label will ever achieve
prominence. Currently, if a producer has a national eco-label that is successful
(Nordic Swan, Blue Angel), there is less of an incentive for them to get the
EU eco-label. These national eco-labels, then, get in the way of the functioning
of a single, common market. The EU in fact admits this,
co-existence with national schemes limits the market value of the Community
eco-label and introduces further complications into its operation. Moreover,
the proliferation of uncoordinated national schemes involves considerable risks
of distortion of the internal market and of competition.
(http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/ecolabel/proprev.htm)
While multiple national schemes may have been fine in the past, the continued
integration of the common market calls for a common eco-label.
The EU can also limit the flow of extraneous information by legislating more
strict standards on private labels. While all European governments have laws
against untruthful advertising, the application of these laws to environmental
considerations has been slow. The ISO 14020 series is a recent international
standard that provides guiding principles for all environmental labels and declarations
and could become a useful tool in regulating these claims (Smallbone, 2000,
2552). Currently, the UK and the Nordic Council (representing the countries
of Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway, and Sweden) are in the process of revising
their national guidelines in light of ISO 14020. The EU should adopt something
similar to the ISO 14020 series that calls for truthful advertising in environmental
claims.
In conclusion, the EU eco-label program faces obstacles but none of which are
insurmountable. The proposed changes of increasing information about the program
and limiting the flow of extraneous information will help solidify the EU eco-label.
The eco-label, then, will be considered a success when these steps of improving
the information provision leads to real environmental improvements as more eco-labeled
products are bought and sold.
Section 4: EMAS
Section 4.1: The Eco-Management and Audit Scheme Regulation
The Eco-Management and Audit Scheme (EMAS) is a voluntary program that attempts
to improve the environment by reducing the pollution caused through the production
of goods. Rather than cleaning up pollution after it has already been created
and released into the environment, EMAS hopes to reduce the amount of waste
generated by manufacturing plants. The focus on the production process means
that the program relies on the efforts of producers to improve the environment.
The regulation aims to
promote continuous improvements in the environmental performance of industrial
activities by:
(a) the establishment and implementation of environmental policies, programmes
and management systems by companies, in relation to their sites;
(b) the systematic, objective and periodic evaluation of the performance of
such elements;
(c) the provision of information of environmental performance to the public
(Council Regulation 1836/93)
The above three objectives are accomplished in a number of ways. First, a company
must write an environmental policy statement that outlines the overall goals
of the companys production process in relation to the environment. Then,
an environmental review of the site occurs from which the firm introduces an
environmental program to address specific problems at the site. Furthermore,
environmental audits of the site must occur to verify that progress is being
made. It is important to note that EMAS simply requires that firms make progress
in reducing the impacts of their activities on the environment. Unlike the eco-label
that establishes an absolute standard of quality, the EMAS program relies on
a standard of relative improvements over past performance. Thus, two firms with
quite different levels of absolute pollution but a similar commitment to improve
in the future can qualify for EMAS. In return for implementing an environmental
management system, firms can hope for a number of benefits. The process of reviewing
and improving their production methods may result in cost savings or lower future
liabilities. More importantly, the EMAS program was sold to firms by arguing
they may expect an increase in the market share of their products from participating
in the program.
Section 4.2: Evaluation of EMAS
The EMAS program can be evaluated on many different levels. The fact that nearly
3,000 sites are registered in EMAS points to a more successful program than
the 200 products plus eco-label program. For this paper, however, the question
is if the information provision of EMAS has led to market effects. It is not
immediately clear, then, that all the sites have joined EMAS in order to capture
the green demand, as there exist many other potential benefits from
joining. The evidence points to a failure of EMAS in using information to turn
the vicious cycle into a virtuous cycle.
An obvious gauge of the success of the information provision is to ask whether
the two players in the exchange, firms and consumers, know about the EMAS program.
Few surveys exist on the level of knowledge of EMAS among management of firms.
A research study by UNI/ASU established that over one quarter of executive managers
did not know about EMAS (Freimann and Schwedes, 1999). Another study by the
Institute for Research in Social Choices identified thirty three percent who
had no knowledge of EMAS and another one third who claimed to know it only partly
(Freimann and Schwedes, 1999). The two studies show that there exists a significant
number of firms that are not aware of the EMAS program. To the best of my knowledge,
there have been no surveys regarding the knowledge of EMAS among the general
public. Through informal talks with people involved with EMAS, including people
who work in the DG Environment in the EMAS program, most admit that there is
near zero knowledge of the EMAS program among the general public. It is clear,
then, that the public dialogue that EMAS attempted to create has not occurred.
The lack of information is partially the result of the limited ability that
firms have in advertising their participation in the program. The EMAS proposal
states that the statement of participation may not be used to advertise
products, or on the products themselves, or on their packaging (Council
Regulation 1836/93). Firms can only advertise their participation in the program
indirectly through press releases and general (non-product specific) advertisements.
This means that in order to benefit from consumer goodwill through participating
in the program, individuals must recall which companies and sites belong to
EMAS when they are shopping. This is probably asking too much of consumers.
Without this public dialogue, there is no mechanism to put pressure on firms
to become clean. Indeed, there have been many studies that confirm
that EMAS has had little to no impact on the market. A study of German participants
of EMAS found that one of the most important facts is that the hopes connected
with participation in the EMAS sometimes did not come up; market effects especially
were rarely noticed (Freimann and Schwedes, 1999). A more comprehensive
study that looked at a random sample of participating firms in all EU countries
asked firms to relate the top three benefits they received from participating
in EMAS. Increased market demand or greater competitive advantage was only cited
by eleven percent of all firms (Hillary, 1998). Six other categories of benefits
were more often cited than competitive advantage. Hence, most firms do not believe
that EMAS is a successful vehicle to capture the demand of green
consumers. The results confirm that without an exchange of information, the
market will continue to operate in the same fashion and will be unable to provide
green goods.
Section 4.3: The future of EMAS?
Section 4.3.1: The EMAS Revision (EMAS2000)
Like the EU eco-label, the Eco-Management and Audit Scheme is undergoing a significant
revision, which seems to be stuck in the EU legislative process. Adopted by
the Commission in October of 1998, it is currently waiting for a second reading
by the European Parliament. The major elements of the revision are as follows
:
- the adoption of a visible and recognizable EMAS logo to allow registered organizations
to publicize their participation in EMAS more effectively
- the strengthening of the role of the environmental statement to improve the
transparency of communication of environmental performance between registered
organizations and their stakeholders and the public
(http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/emas/reference_en.htm)
The adoption of an EMAS logo as well as the stronger environmental statement
are attempts to improve the information exchange between firms and consumers.
Both are positive steps, but probably not strong enough to induce significant
changes in consumer behavior. The new logo should attract the attention of consumers,
but it is unclear how often they will actually see this logo. The revision document
maintains the restrictive guidelines on the use of the label (not allowed on
products or packaging), so firms can only use the logo on company letterhead,
brochures, etc.. In the same way, the stronger environmental statement is a
step in the right direction, but the actual effect will be small since the general
public rarely reads the statement.
Section 4.3.2: Recommendations
The prospect of sustaining and expanding the EMAS program through market effects
of increased information does not seem promising. As seen above, firms currently
experience no market pressure to join EMAS. One may be tempted, then, like in
the case of the eco-label to increase market pressure through increased awareness
of the program. The easiest way to do this would be to loosen the restrictive
advertising and allow firms to directly advertise their participation in EMAS
on their products. While this is a tempting suggestion, I believe it would be
counterproductive. It has the potential to confuse consumers into thinking that
a product produced by an EMAS firm is in fact a green product. Again,
EMAS is a signal of a firms commitment to relative improvements in their
production process, not an absolute claim to the green credentials of a product
over its entire life cycle. Once it is established that firms should not be
able to advertise their participation directly on their product in order to
maintain a distinction with the eco-label, the dim prospects of widespread consumer
knowledge of EMAS must be recognized.
Even if we could somehow ignore the huge problems associated with the exchange
of information and assume individuals had perfect information about EMAS, the
power of the information to lead to market effects seems questionable. This
is because individuals willingness to reward firms for complying with
EMAS may be small for two reasons. First, individuals will be less willing to
reward EMAS firms because the criteria for participation in EMAS are relative.
This is not to say that a green consumer would completely ignore a firms
participation in EMAS. It seems reasonable, however, that consumers would be
less willing to reward firms who are compliant with EMAS than firms who have
an eco-labeled product. A second reason why a perfect information exchange may
still not be strong enough to garner significant market effects goes back to
the public nature of the benefits that participation in EMAS yields. EMAS aims
at improving the environment by reducing pollution in the production process.
These benefits (cleaner water/air) are public as no one can be excluded from
enjoying them, and therefore, the common free-rider problem will arise. While
everyone may enjoy a cleaner environment, there is a tendency to free ride off
of the contribution of others (i.e. let them buy the higher priced EMAS compliant
goods). Some committed individuals may still be willing to pay a premium for
goods with lower environmental impacts, but it is clear that the aggregate willingness
to pay for green goods will be lower due to the free riding problem.
Thus, the fact that the benefits of EMAS participation are public and since
the standard is based on a relative rather than absolute quality level, consumer
willingness to reward firms for such products will be smaller than they would
be otherwise. Add in the major problem of disseminating information about EMAS
without confusing consumers about the eco-label program, and it seems like the
prospects of using the information exchange in EMAS to lead to market effects
is not promising.
Rather than relying on market pressure created through the release of information,
the EU bureaucracy should sell the Eco-Management and Audit Scheme on its other
benefits. According to the firms currently registered in EMAS, one of the top
benefits is cost savings (Hillary, 1998). Especially for small and medium size
enterprises, a thorough and rigorous audit of their production processes can
often lead to cost savings. Another advantage of the audit is that it identifies
when firms are not in compliance with current environmental laws. This allows
firms to address problems and potentially avoid or at least limit future liabilities.
Regular auditing can also create additional cost savings as insurance companies
acknowledge the lower risk of these companies and reward them with lower premiums.
Or, as recently occurred with Deutsche Bank, EMAS registered sites can achieve
cost savings by receiving favorable rates of interest
because (Deutsch
Bank) regards EMAS validation as a clear signal of reduced environmental risks
(Taschner, 1998, 234). A final suggestion is for the EU to focus on links EMAS
can provide within the supply chain. As a few retailers can affect the choices
of a much larger number of consumers, a few large firms can induce change in
their entire web of suppliers below them. For example, Volvo has announced that
it will favor suppliers that are EMAS certified (Taschner, 1998, 221). Depending
on how Volvo interprets EMAS, the requirement to look at their supply chain
may require the suppliers of the suppliers to Volvo to also become EMAS compliant.
If NGOs focus their pressure on large, end product producers and if government
agencies give preferences to EMAS firms in procurement decisions, participation
in the program has the potential to grow at a geometric rate.
Section 5: Conclusion
The ability of an information provision to overcome market failure faces numerous
obstacles, especially when the information concerns the environmental attributes
of a good. Unlike Akerlofs market for used cars, the credence qualities
of green goods mean that experience with the good provides no knowledge
of its characteristics. The EU eco-label and EMAS are government-sanctioned
programs that aim to provide trustworthy information. We have seen, however,
that different objectives and type of information exchanged in each program
greatly affects the ultimate success of the information provision.
The eco-label program holds promise that the exchange of information can lead
to market effects that will improve the environment. The exchange of information
in the program works for a number of reasons. One, the mechanism (the daisy
logo) in which information is transmitted is direct. Consumers can easily access
such information, and with additional time and resources devoted to consumer
education, more consumers will respond to the information and buy eco-labeled
goods. The second advantage of the information exchange in the eco-label program
deals with the type of information transmitted by the daisy. The logo indicates
achievement of an absolute level of quality. A consumer knows that the producer
is one of the cleanest producers in the product group, and they also know that
the overall environmental impact of the product attains a certain level. Finally,
while the eco-label is handicapped by the public nature of several of its benefits,
most eco-labeled goods still result in significant private benefits too. The
combination of private and public benefits is enough to encourage environmentally
conscious consumers to buy such products. Once this demand is exercised, more
producers will have an incentive to produce eco-labeled goods, and this switch
to producing green goods will improve the environment.
The exchange of information in the EMAS program, on the other hand, faces too
many obstacles to become successful in the near future. There are two main obstacles.
First, the restrictive nature of advertising ones participation in EMAS immediately
handicaps the program. This would be difficult to overcome without allowing
advertising directly on products, a step which would introduce the potential
for confusion between the EU eco-label and EMAS programs. The second obstacle
to the EMAS program is that the type of information that EMAS provides is probably
not strong enough to elicit changes in consumer behavior. EMAS, based on a relative
standard of improvement over past performance, says nothing about the true quality
level. When comparing two firms with EMAS certification, it is not clear that
they deserve equal consumer recognition and reward since one firm could have
a much higher level of pollution than the other. Another reason why consumers
may not respond to the information provision of EMAS is because the benefits
one receives from buying a good from an EMAS firm are nearly always public.
The sole focus of EMAS on improving the production methods of firms means that
the benefits from buying a good from an EMAS firm (cleaner air/water) are public,
and the free-rider problem means provision of good is difficult. Nevertheless,
both the eco-label and EMAS programs should be continued. The eco-label, by
maintaining strict absolute standards, is by definition selective and has limited
participation. EMAS, on the other hand, has the potential to reach a wider audience
and can therefore have a bigger impact. Its success, then, should not depend
on the information provision awakening the demand of green consumers
but rather on its other benefits to firms (cost savings, limited future liability).
The EU eco-label and EMAS programs show us that the ability of the market to
self-regulate itself after the provision of new information is a complicated
process. It is not always enough for a government to just provide
information. We have seen that the exchange mechanism, whether a direct mechanism
like the eco-label or an indirect mechanism like in EMAS, can be important in
determining how successful it is in reaching individuals. Another key factor
illustrated in these two programs is that the kind of information is crucial
to its ability to lead to changes in consumer behavior. Stronger pieces of information
(absolute versus relative improvements) and information that has a direct impact
on consumers (private versus public benefits) will more likely yield market
effects. These issues must be addressed when designing voluntary agreements
in the future that attempt to use information to regulate the market.
Figure 1
Works Cited
Akerlof, George. The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty
and the Market Mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (1970): 488-500.
Biondi, Vittorio and Marco Frey. Participation in the EU Eco-Management
and Audit Scheme: An Analysis of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises in Italy.
European Environment 5 (1995):128-133.
Calfee, John and Debra Ringold. Consumer Skepticism and Advertising Regulation:
What Do the Polls Show? Advances in Consumer Research 15 (1988): 244-248.
Commission of the European Communities (1993) Council Regulation (EEC) No 1836/93
of 29 June 1993 allowing voluntary participation by companies in the industrial
sector in a Community eco-management and audit scheme, Official Journal L168,
Vol. 36, 10.7.93.
Commission of the European Communities (1992) Council Regulation (EEC) No 880/92
of 23 March 1992 on a Community eco-label award scheme, Official Journal L099,
11.4.94.
Commission of the European Communities (1996) Council Regulation (EEC) No 880/92
of 10 December 1996 Proposal for a Council Regulation establishing a revised
Community Eco-label Award Scheme, Official Journal Com (96) 603 EN.
Eiderstrom, Eva. Eco-labels in EU Environmental Policy New Instruments
for Environmental Policy in the EU. Ed. Jonathan Colub. New York: Routledge,
1998. 190-214.
Fighting for environmental deregulation: EMAS: way to voluntary deals?
Chemical World 24 May 1995: 37-38.
Franke, Juergen, and Frank Watzold. Political Evolution of EMAS: Perspectives
from the EU, National Governments, and Industrial Groups. European Environment
5 (1995): 155-159.
Freimann, Jurgen and Roswitha Schwedes. EMAS-Experiences in German Companies,
A Survey on Recent Empirical Studies. 1999 Eco-Management and Auditing
Conference Proceedings. ERP Environment, 1999.
Hemmelskamp, Jens, and Karl Ludwig Brockmann. Environmental Labels
The German Blue Angel. Futures 29 (1997): 67-76.
Hillary, Ruth. The Eco-Management and Audit Scheme, A Practical Guide. London:
Stanley Thornes, 1994.
Hillary, Ruth, Matthias Gelber, and Vittorio Biondi. An Assessment of the Implementation
Status of Council Regulation (No 1836/93) Eco-Management and Audit Scheme in
the Member States (AIMS-EMAS) June, 1998.
Hinnells, Mark and Stephen Potter. What Next for Consumer-level Environmental
Policy? Policy Studies Spring (1994): 4-15.
Ippolito, Pauline and Alan Mathios. Information, advertising and health
choice: a study of the cereal market. RAND Journal of Economics 21(1990):
459-480.
Morris, Julian. Green Goods? Consumers, product labels and the environment.
London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1997.
Morris, Louis, Manoj Hastak, and Michael Mazis. Consumer Comprehension
of Environmental Advertising and Labeling Claims. Journal of Consumer
Affairs 29 (1995): 328-350.
OECD. Environmental Labelling in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD, 1991.
Pots, T and F Senesael and M. DeClercq. Promotion and Diffusion of the EU eco-label
in Italy and Benelux. Center for Environmental Economics and Management, 1998.
Re-evaluating eco-labels. Business Europe 15 May 1995: 4-5.
Strachan, Peter, Mamotazul Haque, Alistair McCulloch, and John Moxen. The
Eco-Management and Audit Scheme: Recent Experiences of UK Participating Organizations.
European Environment 7 (1997): 25-33.
Smallbone, Terese. Could the use of ISO 14021 help address the perennial
problem of misleading green product claims? Results of a preliminary ten country
study. 2000 Eco-Management and Auditing Conference Proceedings. ERP Environment,
2000.
Smith, Mark and Stephen Potter. Eco-labelling and Environmental Policy:
Policy Confusion Persists. Policy Studies 17 (1996): 73-80.
Taschner, Karola. Environmental Management Systems: The European Regulation
New Instruments for Environmental Policy in the EU. Ed. Jonathan Colub. New
York: Routledge, 1998. 215-241.
The Roper Organization Inc.. The Environment: Public Attitudes and Individual
Behavior. The Roper Organization, 1990.
Umweltbundesamt. EG-Umweltaudit in Deutschland Erfahrungsbericht
1995 bis 1998.
www.blauer-engel.de
www.europa.eu.int/comm/environment/ecolabel/proprev.htm
www.europea.eu.int/comm/environment/emas
www.europa.eu.int/comm/environment/emas/reference_en.htm