Democratic legitimacy in the EU: the Role of National
Parliaments
Hendrik Vos – Jeroen Decock
hendrik.vos@rug.ac.be
jeroen.decock@rug.ac.be
The influence of parliaments on European decision-making…
… and the search for a new position in the EU
The further structure of this contribution
2. Democracy in the European Union
European unification as democratic project
The involvement of the European population in the EU
policy: new tendencies
The complex relationship between effectiveness and
legitimacy
3. The position of national and
regional parliaments in European decision-making
Decisions and legislative measures
The European integration, which began in
the fifties as an economic story about coal and steel, has become a political
project in the course of the past fifty years. Radical treaty modifications,
which resulted in the Single European Act, the Treaty of Maastricht and (to a
lesser degree) the Treaty of Amsterdam, have considerably extended the radius
of action of what in the meantime has become the European Union (EU).
From the mid eighties
onwards, when completion of the internal market became top priority, the
regulating performance of the European institutions increased considerably: in
the period 1985-1992 alone, the European Commission launched some three hundred
proposals with an eye to the realisation of this internal market. In spite of
the European 'feeling of depression' since Maastricht, this dynamic has not
come to a stop, at least not in the daily EU policy. On the contrary, the
number of policy areas in which the EU acts in a regulating way has only
increased. European regulations are directly applicable in every member state
and directives indeed leave some space for national authorities to emphasise
the things they want, but they are binding in regard to the result that has to
be reached. (art. 249 EG). Also through new methods, such as 'open
co-ordination', Europe sets margins which the member states are supposed to
take into account.
De facto and de jure the member states
have lost sovereignty and they are losing control over policy instruments they
could apply more or less autonomously in the past[i].
Trade policy, environmental policy, transport policy, industrial policy and
many other policy areas were transferred to Europe during the past decades. And
the twelve member states that nowadays form Euroland,
have even parted with their currency policy for once and for all. National
ministers still play an (important!) part concerning decision-making, but
abolition of the veto right in most policy areas that belong to the so-called
'first pillar'[ii], makes that
member states are sometimes confronted with decisions they are overtly against,
but which have to be implemented[iii].
It is very difficult to exactly determine how many percent of the legislation
voted within the member states only (totally or partially) is a translation of
what previously had been decided on European level, but estimations of members
of parliament run to 70 percent (Müller 2000: 210). By the way, it is
striking that parliaments themselves do little research into this matter, or
that little response is given to this. Maybe there is a fear introspection
might lead to relativisation of the own activities.
The
influence of parliaments on European decision-making…
It has to be said that parliaments in
general are only marginally involved in European decision-making (Norton 1996:
27). In the Western vision on democracy parliaments nevertheless form crucial
links: they are traditionally considered as the locus of democratic decision-making. The concrete interpretation
differs from state to state, but basically it is a fact that in parliamentary
democracies laws are made and amended by a parliament that also controls the
government in its exertion of the executive power.
For a long time nobody worried about the
democratic standard of the European construction: there was a 'permissive
consensus' (Katz 1999: 23). This changed gradually when it became clear that
the European regulations – how technical they might look at first sight – involve
political choices: about the relation between ecology and economy, about the
importance of cultural diversity, about the range of social topics and of
liberalisation, about agriculture and development etc. All directives and
regulations reflect in a certain way political choices and priorities and
especially a vision of how European society has to look like. Today most
(national and regional) parliaments have determined that their traditional
power has seriously eroded. (Rideau 1996: 161, 169; Kassim 2000b: 257): they
are as it were 'obliged' to vote certain laws and a considerable number of
European directives is converted into national law by the executive power.
Sometimes the impression is created that parliaments nowadays only interfere
with trivial things, with fiddling in the margin, while real decisions escape
control. Moreover, in the European treaties there is no room for national and
regional parliaments[iv].
Research shows that members of parliaments
are everything but happy with the democratic character of European
decision-making (Wessels 1999b: 213). The loss of parliamentary influence on
national level was not compensated by the foundation of similar structures on
European level. There is indeed a European Parliament that has got considerably
more power than before and its influence is often underestimated, but this
European Parliament did not take over the traditional functions of national
parliaments. In the best case the European Parliament is co-legislator
(together with the Council of Ministers), but it does not dispose of the right
of initiative and the control over the executive power is more limited, among
others because there is no European 'government' (in the classical meaning of
the word) (Thomassen, Schmitt 1999: 131). The question rises whether it is
realistic and useful to give the European Parliament on European level a
similar role as national parliaments. Realistic, because this would turn the EU
into a federal construction, what for a lot of member states is not a policy
option (at the moment) (Andersen, Eliassen 1996: 3). Useful, because the EU is
quite a special construction: maybe other recipes are needed to increase
democratic legitimacy than a classic parliamentary approach. In other words,
how useful is it to consider traditional parliamentary democracy as a blueprint
of the model the EU has to evolve to if it wants to be considered legitimate.
We will come back to this later.
…
and the search for a new position in the EU
The influence of national and regional
parliaments on European decision-making seems very limited today. At the same
time, a need is experienced to hype up the EU legitimacy. Especially in the
nineties the term democratic deficit was used a lot. Referenda about the
Maastricht Treaty were in general not a huge success, opinion polls show that
the average European does not really feel involved in the European project, the
turnout at the European elections in 1999 went below 50 percent, in June 2001
the Irish rejected the Treaty of Nice and in September 2000 the Euro was
rejected by the Danes. Slogans during demonstrations at European top meetings
were clear.
It is often said that parliaments will have
to contribute to the legitimisation of the European project. In the Convention,
founded in December 2000 during the Laeken European Council, this topic is an
important subject of conversation. This Convention thinks about the future of
Europe, in preparation for a treaty modification (which will probably be
negotiated about in the second half of 2003 or in 2004). Two representatives of
each (national) parliament participate in the talks. The Laeken Declaration, in
which more or less an agenda was set up for the convention debates, mentions
the matter explicitly and formulates a diversity of questions:
“The national parliaments
also contribute towards the legitimacy of the European project. The declaration
on the future of the Union, annexed to the Treaty of Nice, stressed the need to
examine their role in the European integration.
[…]
A […] question,
which also relates to democratic legitimacy, involves the role of national
parliaments. Should they be represented in a new institution, alongside the
Council and the European Parliament? Should
they have a role in areas of European action in which the European Parliament
has no competence? Should they focus on the division of competence between
Union and member states, for example through preliminary checking of compliance
with the principle of subsidiarity?”
A lot of thought is put into the position
parliaments will take in the EU of tomorrow. The questions from the Laeken
Declaration, but also many others, create a framework for the debate. That
parliaments still have a role to play seems to be the starting point of the
European heads of state and government who drew up the Laeken Declaration.
(Vos, Baillieul 2002: 24-25). It is in this vein that ‘Convention Working Group
IV on the role of national parliaments’ was set up (Final Report: CONV 353/02).
The further structure of this contribution
When parliaments are concerned, we are
talking about democracy. In the first part we take a look at what democracy
means in the EU. The next part deals with European decision-making: we work out
for various types of European decisions and various phases in decision-making the
role parliaments (could) play today. From this survey we will be able to deduct
concrete suggestions about how reinforcement of the influence of parliaments
could hype up the democratic standard of the EU.
2.
Democracy in the European Union
Sometimes 'democracy' is wrongly reduced to
'governance by the people'. This rather formalistic interpretation deals with
the modus operandi and is an
important aspect of democracy, but it can never be isolated. In scientific
literature one talks of both formalistic democracy and of a result oriented
aspect: a democratic policy is an effective policy (Gustavsson 1996: 104, 111;
Andersen, Eliassen 1996: 9). Some authors talk in this respect about input and
output democracy: democracy from input side means that as many voices as
possible should be heard concerning the realisation of policy, while democracy
on output side means that the policy should be 'good' for as many people as
possible (Peterson, Shackleton 2002: 356). Two of the most often quoted
researchers on this topic, say it as follows:
“Democratic
legitimation rests both on the effectiveness of policy achievements and on
popular representation and participation. Democracy as an ideal combines these
two criteria of governance and representation that are often seen being in
tension. […] There is an inevitable trade-off between output legitimacy and
input legitimacy, between an emphasis on government for the people and an emphasis on government by the people […]” (Wessels, Katz 1999: 5)
Below we first talk about the importance of
the EU in a pursuit of an output democracy (or substantial democracy). Then we
discuss the involvement of the European population in the Union policy (or
formal democracy). Afterwards we round up the news.
European
unification as democratic project
We have just said that an effective policy is an important aspect
of democratic governance: present problems have to be dealt with. A lot of present-day problems have an
international dimension. Environmental problems are a good example: water and
air pollution do not stop at borders, global warming does not only affect those
people who are responsible for it and the hole in the ozone layer is not
situated right above those who use CFCs. But also terrorism is an example of a
problem that is impossible to deal with within each state separately. Because
of inherent international aspects of present-day problems an international
approach is necessary. Effective answers to these challenges ask for an
integrated policy.
Moreover, a lot of present-day problems are
linked to what we nowadays call 'globalisation': deterritorialisation of
economic, cultural and technological processes. National governments have
little grip on these processes that are strongly linked to the functioning of
the free market economy. This leads to a democratic deficit. Nevertheless, for
ideological or pragmatic reasons, the free market economy is being defended by
most states, although it leads to a certain loss of power. During a conference
of the chairmen of the national parliaments of the EU in Lisbon (1999) about
the challenge of globalisation, one of the speakers talked about the end of the
primate of politics[v]. If
democracy means that people influenced by the decisions, have to be involved in
the realisation of these decisions (input democracy, see further), then a huge
problem arises. In reality, investment decisions which are made in the head
offices of transnational enterprises affect the lives of many thousands of
people: their income, their employment, their health, the environment in their
neighbourhood etc. In a free market economy increasing the profit is generally
the most important criterion for investment decisions. Governments are being
forced to a certain extent to anticipate this: creating a friendly climate for
investment often becomes the leading thread in the policy (to that extent that
some wonder whether they are not too enthusiastic about it – this is of course
not the subject of this contribution). Anyway, it sometimes seems very
difficult for an individual state to pursue an isolated policy and to enforce
unilateral rules that are linked with social justice, protection of nature, tax
law etc. (Österud 1996: 179). The government has less grip on economy, what
does not make it powerless, but what seriously restricts its freedom of action.
Nowadays, ‘national sovereignty’ is in many respects an illusion; a myth that
does well in political rhetoric, but results to be quite weak after a test.
Ignolf Pernice, a prominent academic of the
Humboldt University in Berlin, sees it like this:
“States are no
longer able to meet the challenges they stand for. To ensure external and
internal security, welfare and the protection of human rights, to govern global
markets and the international financial system, to combat climate change,
international crime and terrorism, supranational and international systems of
governance are needed which go beyond traditional forms of co-operation between
sovereign states.” (Pernice
2001: 9)
The only democratic answer to on the one
hand (economic) globalisation processes and on the other hand the conclusion
that many problems have an international dimension, is political globalisation:
determining the rules of the game on a higher level than that of the
traditional state. The democratic deficit that appears on the level of the
states can (at least partially) be filled by creating strong international and
supranational institutions which can 'guide' international processes, where
separate states cannot (Wessels, Kielhorn 1999: 176). In an ideal scenario it
could concern global governance, for
example within the framework of the United Nations. In real terms, this is not
very simple and a lot of states are not prepared to reconcile to political
decisions that are taken on a higher level. Within Europe this does work to
some extent. The EU is an interesting 'laboratory' for global governance. For
the solution of certain problems a regional (European) approach can be
sufficient. Moreover, the EU is – among others because of its economic strength
– also capable of speaking with more authority and effect than the member
states separately. The EU policy anticipates the globalisation trend and
facilitates this process (the creation of an internal market with free trade of
capital and goods etc.). In this field Europe has showed itself extremely
effective during the last decades. But at the same time rules are being imposed
(although very often in a hesitating way[vi]),
among others concerning competition, the environment and in the social field.
This is in line with a couple of values large parts of the European public
opinion consider as important. Recently, Peterson and Shackleton summarised the
situation very clearly:
“Above all, the
problem of governing the global economy, in a political world where most
governments believe in the virtues of open commerce, requires global rules and
the adjudication of conflicting interests. In this context, the European Union
may be seen as an essential, driving force behind the freeing of international
trade […]. At the same time, the EU remains a staunch defender of values that
are easily trammelled by free trade, such as environmental protection or core
labour standards.” (Peterson,
Shackleton 2002: 365)
From a democratic point of view it is
desirable that there is a strong political Europe that speaks with one voice in
the world and that lays down norms in the social, fiscal and environmental
field, just because the individual states do not have (full) power to pursue an
effective policy. This is the only way to gain more democratic control over
extremely important processes. But the EU lacks something. The EU does act in
an energetic way in the free market area, but it does not succeed very well in
guaranteeing social and ecological protection, creating employment and dealing
with unfair fiscal competition. Some member states are very reluctant against
European legislature concerning these domains. Nevertheless, from democratic
perspective it is desirable that Europe acts effectively here: not free of
obligations, not with half compromises, not with extremely chaotic and complex
legislation or with years of delay. To play the ball quickly and to act
energetically, we need compelling rules and supranational decision-making
(Österud 1996: 179; Smith 1996: 11). This implies that member states have to
transfer power to European institutions, such as the Commission (as
representative of the 'European
interest') and the European Parliament and that decisions are not taken
unanimously but with a majority of votes. We learn that decisions are made more
easily this way than when the intergovernmental method is being used, where
every member state keeps its veto and the role of the Commission is limited.
That the EU is sometimes perceived as
non-democratic, does not only have to do with the fact that it does not act
powerful enough in some areas, but probably also with conceptualisation: Europe
is often depicted as the bogeyman by the media. National or regional
politicians have the tendency to blame Europe for everything that goes wrong,
but not rarely will they try to put the feathers of European policy in their
own caps.
But we are deviating from the subject. Legitimacy of European institutions shall only really increase when it is clear that the policy they pursue is in accordance with what the European population wants and thinks is important. Now we have reached the second aspect of democracy: the policy has to be a reflection of what the majority of the population wants.
The
involvement of the European population in the EU policy: new tendencies
That processes occur the population has no
grip on via the classic channel of the states (because the states neither have
a grip on these processes), cannot be an excuse to ignore every type of
participation on the level of the EU. On the contrary, says the Norwegian
political scientist Öyvind Österud: “the number one challenge to supranational
integration is popular legitimation of institutions and decision-making at this
level.” (Österud 1996: 179). But there appears to be a problem here: opinion
polls, the results of referenda and the turnout at European elections show that
a large part of the European population is indifferent (in the best case), but
often sceptical and sometimes hostile towards European institutions[vii].
For the most part, the news coverage of European measures (especially in the
popular press) is not such that this will change. Nevertheless, the European
policy can be influenced effectively through various channels. But it is all
not as clear – at least at first sight – as it is in the member states. There
parliaments are the corner stones of democracy: in election time the population
chooses parties which represent a more or less coherent programme. Then a
government is formed that pursues a policy that is supported by a majority in
the national or regional parliament. There are no European political parties
(yet), the European Parliament is not the only legislator in the EU and does
not play the part national or regional parliaments play in the formation of the
government. In fact there is no such thing as a European government. But this
does not mean that democratic control on European decision-making is
impossible.
Some authors say that there is a “system of dual representation” in the
EU (Hilf, Burmeister 1996: 65). It means that two (parliamentary) channels
watch over legitimacy of European decision-making. In the first place national
(and sometimes regional) parliaments can exert influence and control on the
activities of 'their' ministers in the Council. This gets some researchers to
speak of “national parliaments as cornerstones of European integration” (Smith
1996). We will come back to the role of national parliaments later. Secondly,
also the European Parliament plays a decisive part in most areas that belong to
the so-called first (originally economic) pillar: parliament disposes in most
cases of the power of co-decision. With politically delicate topics such as tax
law, parts of the agricultural and employment policy etc. this is not the case,
neither as in the second (foreign and security policy) or third (police and
judicial co-operation in criminal matters) pillar. In these areas the role of
the European Parliament is very limited. But in the 'daily European policy' the
European Parliament disposes of a lot of power: it is capable of blocking
regulations and often succeeds in seriously amending proposals of the
Commission. Moreover, the Commission takes into account the position the
European Parliament shall probably take when it concerns the drawing up of
proposals. In those areas where the co-decision procedure is used, the European
Parliament is more powerful than is often assumed[viii].
It should increase legitimacy of European decision-making considerably if on
the one hand the field of application of the co-decision procedure should be
extended to fields where Parliament nowadays can only be heard or in the worst
case be informed and if on the other hand it is made clear to the European
population that this Parliament really is decisive in numerous files.
But we cannot get around it: in the
European decision-making process many important steps are taken that escape
direct democratic control by national and European parliaments (also in those
areas where the European Parliament is co-decision-maker). We can for example
think about 'policy conception' (the phase preceding the introduction of a
proposal by the Commission into Council or Parliament), setting of the agenda,
a part of the policy execution (among others comitology procedures) or the
crucial talks in council working groups (mentioned in the treaty or not). The
role of the European Parliament in these phases is limited and the exact role
of national governments is not always very clear. Moreover, the Commission acts
(de jure) independently from these
governments. Member states are confronted with political activities they cannot
directly control (Wessels, Katz 1999: 11). But on which considerations are the
decisions of for example the Commission based? And is there not even one link
to the 'will' of the European population? The answer is subtle.
Every decision (policy building,
policy-making, policy executing) is the result of formal and informal
negotiations in which various interests are balanced. When we talk about
interests, a difference has to be made between a territorial and a functional
dimension (Wessels 1999a: 128): there is the interest of a specific state or
region (for example concerning the division of subsidies or the provision for
certain social acquisitions), but there are also more specific interests that
are often linked to certain groups (interests of farmers, employees in the
public sector, car designers, consumers, animal rights activists etc.). There
is of course a certain overlap between both dimensions: a national or regional
member of parliament is estimated to defend national or regional (territorial)
interests, but can often also be associated with specific functional interests,
among others via the political party he or she belongs to. Besides, lobby groups
will actively try to convince members of parliament (on regional, national or
European level) of their interest, to have more power in the decision-making
process[ix].
Functional defence of interests is very
important in Europe. European decision-making includes more and more areas and
is often of a technical nature – although basically political-ideological
choices lie at the bottom of this. Negotiations about one directive or
regulation last for months, often years and are extremely complex. It becomes very
difficult for members of (national, regional but also European) parliaments to
master all the points of view and ins and outs of the multitude of processes,
problems and challenges that are brought to them in one concrete measure. Time
and technical knowledge are lacking here. The judgement of Andersen and Burns
is hard: “They [parliaments; hv] fail to provide the problem-solving capability
for dealing with […] the spectrum of contemporary governance problems.”
(Andersen, Burns 1996: 243) A consequence of this is that directly interested
parties will want to be heard directly. Intermediary organs, which bundle
interests, have become very important in the EU (Greenwood 1997). In the course
of the past decades we have determined that a huge flock of lobbyists has
invaded the neighbourhood of the Schumanplein
in Brussels.
Important parts of decision-making are negotiated about in all kinds of functional networks. The European Commission also encouraged the expansion of these networks: in the policy preparing phase it gets a better picture of what 'lives' under the numerous directly interested parties. That way it can come forward with more realistic proposals. Moreover, for elementary information the Commission is often dependent on the actors in that field.
That decisions are largely based on what
happens within the networks does not mean that there is no link between the
population and European institutions. On the contrary, a European citizen is
namely also consumer, member of a union or an ecology group or depends for
employment on a company that has a lobby office in Brussels. Its interests are
given a chance, but of course they are balanced against the interests of other
groups. Some talk in this respect about ‘deliberative democracy’: as many
voices as possible are heard and preferably all interests that are 'affected'
by a specific proposal are involved in the design phase of this proposal
(Newman 2001: 370-371).
These steps in the policy-making process
have become so important that some talk about the end of parliamentary
democracy. Functional organisations (such as interest groups) replace
territorial representatives (members of parliament)[x].
Basically it still concerns democracy, meaning that the policy is based on what
lives in society, but it is filled differently: now it concerns negotiations
between various (functionally organised) interests, without (territorial)
parliaments playing an important part. In academic literature it is sometimes
thought that this evolution will continue: “the most likely future appears to
be a decline of parliamentary democracy” (Wessels, Katz 1999: 14). Andersen and
Burns talk about post-parliamentary democracy and mean the following:
“[…] formal
parliamentary arrangements and decision-making are replaced to a large extent
by the principle that directly affected parties have the right to participate
in and influence policy- and law-making. This is the basis for
self-representation and specialised representation in particular policy
networks or sub-governments.” (Andersen, Burns 1996: 234-235)
It is probably a little bit too early to
speak of the final end of parliamentary democracy, but it does not alter the
fact that there is a shift in decision-making: from parliamentary bodies to
groups and networks, in which public and private actors negotiate. When
representatives of the governments are involved in policy networks (what mostly
is the case), it seems very difficult for parliament to exert control.
A crucial question is whether democracy per se has to be organised through
parliaments. Are parliaments not rather a means to reach democracy instead of
an aim in itself? If it showed that post-parliamentary democracy works
perfectly and leads to the fact that the voice of the European population is
translated correctly and equally into the European policy, then it is not only
very legitimate to acknowledge the surplus value of this type of government
with the development and execution of the policy, but also to leave final
responsibility for decisions, important ideological choices and the stipulation
of general policy lines to post-parliamentary democracy and its methods and
institutions. In that case there should be no reason any more to search for a
new role for parliaments, only because of the members of parliaments and their
livelihood. But we find that on the one hand parliaments still have a role to
play or anyway could have a role to play in the European decision-making
process (we will come back to this later) and that on the other hand criticism
can be passed on the functioning of post-parliamentary democracy. The most
fundamental criticism is that some groups succeed more quickly in taking part
in this new type of governance than others. Also Andersen and Burns realise
this:
“In this type of
governance, economically well-endowed groups as well as highly organised groups
and impassioned movements with focused interests can concentrate on specialised
policy areas of particular concern to them (Andersen, Burns 1996: 246)
Put differently, some interests are for numerous
reasons not organised strongly enough to take part in decision-making[xi].
Via among others subsidy decisions this is somewhat corrected in the EU
(various NGOs get for example support from the European Commission), but far
from completely. Moreover, it is normal that most interest groups aim for
short-term interests. When looking for compromises between these interests a
long-term broader perspective seems to go lost. We shall argument that
parliaments definitely have a role to play in this field.
Finally we have some remarks. We have to
wonder whether the shift in power of parliamentary bodies to informal groups
and networks is actually new. Maybe decision-making occurred in the same way in
the past, but less openly and maybe an illusion of parliamentary power was
maintained. We do not pay much further attention to this matter. The following
remark has to do with the position of democracy within the member states. If we show up the lack of democracy
within the EU, we have to be careful that we do not idealise the situation in
the member states. Although it is exaggerated to say that national politics
only deals with trivial matters, we have to repeat that many crucial policy
decisions are no longer made by the member states. Secondly, informal networks
also play an important part on the level of the member states, although it is
not always as clear as on the European level. The above mentioned phenomenon of
a shift in power does not limit itself to the EU: lobbying or various forms of
corporatism can also be found elsewhere (Andersen, Eliassen 1996: 7). When
Andersen and Burns (1996) talk about the erosion of parliamentary democracy,
they also refer to democracy in the member states. Finally, research shows that
national and regional parliaments have lost a lot of power, mostly to the
advantage of governments (Norton 1996; Dewachter 1997: 25-42; Wessels, Kielhorn
1999: 190; Andersen, Eliassen 1996: 4). Although the situation differs from
country to country, many researchers are very pessimistic when the real power
of national and regional parliaments is concerned. We should not conclude too
easily that within the member states national parliaments are the centre of
power and authority. A number of rituals contribute to this feeling (Andersen,
Burns 1996: 244): every few years the population elects a parliament, that
parliament seems to make decisions about numerous cases, the government seems
to be accountable to parliament and if something goes wrong we start looking
for politically responsible persons. But can the real power in the member
states be found in the parliaments? Or has this also become a myth?
The
complex relationship between effectiveness and legitimacy
The population expects politics to give
answers to present-day problems. A lot of these problems have an international
dimension and ask for solutions states cannot formulate separately any more. We
thus need a strong Europe. A Europe that is energetic, flexible and that can
adapt quickly and preferably with full knowledge to challenges. Although
ultimate decisions are still made by the Council of Ministers (together with
the European Parliament or not) it is in this context that a type of government
emerges in which all kinds of involved parties participate in policy-making and
policy executing through networks. The power of this type of governance is
based on its relative effectiveness. Defence of interests occurs to a large
extent on functional basis. If representatives of regions or member states are
involved, their mandate is often not strictly fenced off (the way of working
does not allow this); parliamentary debates are mostly non-existing. Although
numerous interests that live in Europe find their way to the decision-making
process, there is a feeling of 'lack of legitimacy': the notorious democratic
deficit.
The legitimacy problem is also in another
way under discussion: a powerful European policy is irreconcilable with a
decision-making procedure in which the parties involved formally dispose of a
veto. If the Council has to vote every measure unanimously, the machine blocks.
Who pleads for a European performance in a certain policy area, has to accept
that he/she can be confronted with decisions there is no support for in a
certain member state or region. This is the logic of the community method and
the only way to guarantee progress: if there is unanimity about the aims (as
they are mentioned in the treaties), we have to agree to the fact that – for
realising these aims – some specific measures have to be taken which are less
popular in certain regions or member states. This may cause the problem that
the inhabitants of this region or member state do not feel involved, especially
if there is a perception of being treated unfairly systematically. Here again the legitimacy problem emerges.
So, there is a certain tension between two
aspects of democracy: the need for an effective policy leads to a way of
decision-making that can be experienced as less legitimate. Andersen and
Eliassen explain it very clearly:
“The legitimacy
of political systems is normally dependent upon an acceptable mixture between
representativity and effectiveness. These two dimensions may be mutually
supportive, but there are also elements of conflict.” (Andersen, Eliassen 1996: 9-10)
We are thus seeking for ways to improve the
relationship between the European policy and the things that live among the
population of the member states and regions[xii].
The consequent application of the subsidiarity principle is important in this
case (we will come back to this later), but in a world in which national or
regional sovereignty has become very relative, we see that a strong European
governance is necessary in numerous areas. And exactly then we have to weigh
things. Smith talks about the weighing off of costs:
“What is a reasonable
price to pay when exchanging a higher degree of democracy for possibly less
effective fulfilment of the aims for which the supranational decision-making
mechanisms within the EU have been adopted?” (Smith 1996: 15)
The more participation (e.g. concerning
parliaments), the more slowly decision-making occurs and the more 'blocking
possibilities' there are and summed up in short: the less European policy.
Nevertheless, it is not correct to see this as a zero-sum game in which participation and effectiveness exclude each
other and more participation leads to the fact that there is less effectiveness
or vice versa. The relation is much more complex: if the EU policy
systematically does not find connection to what lives in the member states and
regions, the integration process would suffer a lot from this. You cannot
unpunished saddle member states or regions with the execution of decisions they
have never been involved in. As we will argue later on, parliaments (not only
the European, but also national and regional parliaments) can play a crucial
role in increasing legitimacy of the EU policy. How big the surplus value of
informal networks might be, the need for political final responsibility stays,
the long-term perspective has to be taken into account[xiii],
fundamental (maybe ideological) choices have to be made and we have to see to
it that also less strongly organised groups are thought about.
Before we discuss the role of national and
regional parliaments we have some comments on the European Parliament. Who aims
for a more democratic EU cannot go round the fact that a reinforcement of the
European Parliament is important[xiv].
This parliament is the only directly elected institution in the EU. In
contradiction to other parliaments, the power of this European Parliament has
grown over the last few years, but the limited involvement of this parliament
in crucial policy decisions in the first, second and third pillar leads to a
democratic deficit. More final responsibility can definitely be given to the
directly elected members of this parliament, without affecting the
effectiveness of decision-making. A generalisation of the co-decision procedure
should be a huge step forward. National parliaments sometimes see the European
Parliament as a competitor (Cygan 2001: xv). This is in some respects unjust.
As it will appear later, when we scrutinise the role of national and regional
parliaments, all parliaments have their role in enforcing the legitimacy of
European decisions and they are very complementary. It is for example not very
realistic to suppose that the European Parliament should get the same role
within the European construction as national parliaments in national politics.
Moreover, many authors point out the fact that there is no European 'demos':
Europeans shall only perceive the European Parliament as 'their'
parliament when they really consider themselves Europeans. But there are important
cultural differences within the Union and interests can differ a lot. This is
also the case on national or regional level, but on European level it is seen
on a larger scale (and maybe there is also a historic inheritance: only a few
decades ago wars divided Europe) (Smith 1996: 13). All in all there are few
'European organisations' the population can connect to and that could
contribute to a European citizenship. There are no European political parties
yet[xv]
and European elections still concern national topics. Possibly the Euro can
have an effect on the feeling of being a European citizen. We also have to
emphasise that the distance between the elected and his electors on European
level is very huge: Wessels calculated that in the national parliaments there
is one elected person per 54.844 inhabitants, while one European member of
parliament represents 429.729 inhabitants (Wessels 1999a: 106). So for various
reasons, the European Parliament cannot immediately take over all functions of
the other parliaments. Who wants to enforce democracy in Europe cannot only pay
attention to the European Parliament. Also the parliaments of the regions and
member states have an important role to play.
3.
The position of national and regional parliaments in European decision-making
In this part we take a look at the role
national and regional parliaments play or could
play nowadays in European decision-making. We evaluate these possibilities
on the basis of conclusions from the previous part: a strong Europe and strong
European institutions are perfectly reconcilable with a striving for democracy,
but at the same time attention has to be paid to participation and involvement
of the population of the member states.
In this overview we give a rather general
image and we do not extensively discuss the various ways participation is dealt
with in separate member states and regions. Sometimes there are separate
arrangements in different pillars and for specific policy areas, among others
concerning transparency, that (could) influence the role of national and
regional parliaments. Here we restrict ourselves to generalisations and put emphasis
on the first pillar (where most of EU activity takes place), but most
conclusions are also valid for the second and third pillar. We do make a
difference between various types of decisions: in the first place it concerns
treaty modifications and legislative decisions. We also pay attention to the
very important prelegislative story and finally we discuss (in short) the
execution of the decisions.
The method that is traditionally used to
revise treaties, is that of the Intergovernmental Conference (IGC) (art. 48 EU): representatives of
the governments of the member states negotiate during a couple of months in a
very private atmosphere about the treaty revision, whereupon heads of state and
government cut the final knot at a European Council. The text of the treaty
that has come into being that way has to be ratified by all member states. How
this occurs exactly, is arranged by every member state separately. But we see
that national parliaments deal with the ratification, although in some member
states also the population can vote about it in referenda. Generally speaking,
members of parliament thus vote about basic treaties and the amendments made to
them. In Belgium both the approval of the federal parliament (Chamber and
Senate) and of the five regional parliaments is required. In some other federal
states regions also are involved in this because the federal Chamber (such as
the German Bundesrat, in which
regional ministers are seated) has to vote about the revision of treaties. Nowhere
else the influence of regional parliaments is arranged as directly as in
Belgium.
Although the parliaments involved in the
ratification in theory dispose of a lot of power (they can prevent even one
comma from being shifted, deleted or added to treaties), there is – precisely
in the parliaments – a lot of dissatisfaction about the procedure for revising
treaties. In practice, an agreement is made between the governments of the
member states which is presented to the parliaments as 'take it or leave it'. A
refusal of ratification would immerse the EU in a constitutional crisis
(Raunio, Hix 2001: 142). De facto the
power of the parliaments is not that huge, although representatives of the
government anticipate the probable reaction of the parliaments during the
negotiations: they make sure they do not make decisions that are absolutely
unacceptable for the home base (Munro 1996: 92). Sometimes, under impulse of
for example the national parliamentary committee that deals with European
affairs, a national or regional parliamentary debate is organised, but in real
terms we notice that these debates are often superficial and that the same
mantras are only repeated. This type of debate can give government negotiators
a general sense of direction, but it can hardly guide them with the concrete
negotiations.
In Nice it was decided that a new method to
prepare treaty revisions is desirable. National parliaments should be more
involved in this. As an answer to this the European Council of Laeken set up a
Convention. In this Convention representatives of the parliaments play an
important part: each national parliament sends two delegates (as opposed to one
representative of the government per member state). Moreover, also the European
Parliament is represented well by sixteen members. Regional parliaments are not
directly involved (although a member state is free to admit a representative of
an executive parliament in the two-man parliamentary delegation). But the
Committee of the Regions did appoint six observers: representatives of the
regions and local governments. It is the task of the Convention to think about
the future of the EU (under the terms of enlargement) and to prepare the next
IGC (planned for 2003 or 2004). If the Convention comes up with clear points of
view, preferably concrete text proposals of a European Constitution, it will be
very difficult for the representatives of the government in the IGC to ignore
this point of view. A process has been started where an important participation
of parliaments is planned. Or better: for the representatives the parliaments
have appointed. We have to mention that the convention formula is not new: it
has been used earlier for drawing up the European Charter of Fundamental
Rights. The delegates of the national parliaments were also represented best
here, but in most member states it did not lead to long parliamentary debates.
On the contrary, most representatives worked in a way that isolated them from
'their' parliament. So, we cannot speak of a permanent feedback process. The
convention formula offers possibilities to get a broader parliamentary debate
going about important aspects of European integration, but it is not a
guarantee in itself. It is up to the parliaments to organise the debate and
give inspiration (maybe even a mandate) to the representatives. It is not very
useful if this parliamentary debate restricted itself to repeating the mantras
that have been in use for decades. In that case parliamentary involvement is a
rather boring spectacle. Eventually the representatives will end up in a very
dynamic negotiation process, where they are confronted with the often very
diverse opinions of other participants. From superficial debates little
inspiration can be drawn and in concrete issues
they shall sometimes take points of view that are not necessarily based on the
parliamentary debate. If parliaments really want to take up the debate about
treaty modifications (and more in general about Europe's future), the whole
negotiation process and the dynamic that lives in the Convention, have to be
followed strictly and members of parliament shall have to take into account the
visions of other regions and member states. An involvement of national and
regional parliaments in important and historic European processes has to be
encouraged from a democratic point of view.
In the end it also concerns the future of national and regional
politics. Involvement in these processes and providing a certain guidance
(although it will be difficult to fully win the argument in this dynamic
process) is probably more important than disposing of an ultimate veto during
the ratification procedure.
About the importance of this ultimate veto
one can judge in various ways from a democratic point of view. In a certain way
it is the ultimate means of control, but it has to be said that it does not
mean that much in practice, just because it is 'yes' or 'no'; an intermediate
position is not possible. If there were ratification problems, it could have to
do with internal political tensions in the member state concerned, and not
necessarily with the case in itself. Since the Single European Act we have
noticed that treaty modifications occur in a more rapid succession and it
becomes a tough job to get the ratification done before the next IGC starts. In
their report for the Commission on the institutional consequences of the
enlargement, Richard Von Weizsäcker, Jean-Luc Dehaene and David Simon (1999)
point out the fact that the continuous treaty modifications are a source of
political difficulties in various member states[xvi].
In an extended Union in which every treaty modification should be treated in
twenty-five or more parliamentary systems, there is a danger for delays and
risks for a complete paralysis. If one pleads for a Europe that can anticipate
important new challenges, then the present arrangement is no longer tenable.
Nevertheless, it can be expected that a 'basic treaty', let us say a
constitution, in which for example the general aims and guidelines, the rights
of citizens and the institutional framework are inserted, has to be endorsed by
all parliaments. With approving the ‘basic treaty’ the parliaments of the
member states acknowledge the surplus value of the European integration process
and they indicate that they acknowledge the general aims. It is important that
this acceptation occurs explicitly and the ratification procedure is probably
the best guarantee for this. The other parts of present treaties translate the
general aims in the various policy areas. Since the mid eighties these parts
have to be amended quite regularly to give the EU the chance to effectively
anticipate the new challenges. Subjecting all these modifications to an
exhausting ratification process in all parliaments hypothecates a swift and
vigorous European action. The suggestion from the Von
Weizsäcker, Dehaene and Simon report to assimilate these elements in separate
texts that can be amended in accordance to a less difficult procedure
(unanimously or with a superqualified majority in the (European) Council, and
certainly with the involvement of the European Parliament), is very
interesting. National (and for Belgium also regional) parliaments lose their
veto right and do no longer have to ratify these texts (which are just below
the constitution). But on the other hand, the Union (of which the general aims
are accepted by each parliament) gains on power and credibility. Moreover, a
convention formula (that is possibly institutionalised better) can expressly
provide for an involvement of parliaments when changing these texts. And as
said before, the involvement in the process and the signals that can be given
in an early stadium could become more important and effective than the threat
of a veto that can only be declared after the negotiations.
Decisions
and legislative measures
If decisions are taken in the line of the
second or third pillar (art. 22, 34 EU) or directives, regulations or decisions
are concluded (art. 249 EG), the Council always plays a key role (together with
the European Parliament or not, cf. infra). In the Council, ministers of
fifteen member states meet. They are not directly elected and negotiate in a
rather closed atmosphere[xvii].
The meetings are prepared by a Permanent Representatives Committee (coreper)
that bases itself on discussions in numerous working groups, in which the
member states are represented. The members of these working groups are often
experts from the administration or diplomats connected to the Permanent
Representation to the EU (let us say the embassy of an EU member state). A
direct parliamentary control on what happens in the council working groups and
the coreper is lacking. For the ministers, who eventually cut the knot, this
can be different: each minister has a responsibility for his deeds to 'his'
national parliament. In this field there was a kind of 'permissive consensus'
for a long time (Katz, Wessels 1999: 245): most parliaments did not interfere
with European affairs and ministers could do what they wanted in the European
meetings. When parliaments realised that European politics had an impact on
their powers, this changed. In all member states and in some regions
parliaments have already founded committees concerning European affairs
(Raunio, Hix 2000: 156). The exact powers and the impact differ from state to state
(Smith, Eivind 1996; Kassim 2000b: 240). Some of these committees concentrate
on almost every measure that has to be discussed by the Council, while other
committees only follow the general guidelines of Europolitics and can in the
best case discuss points that are dealt with on European meetings of heads of
state and government. The most extreme model consists of a minister asking a
mandate for every session of the Council, in which can be found how far the
minister can go in the negotiations and when he has to vote for or against. For
various reasons, which we will discuss later, this extreme system is not
applied anywhere. In Denmark it is probably approached best.
If parliaments
want to keep an eye on things and want to follow the activities of their
minister in the Council, it is of course important that they dispose of enough
information. A protocol (no.9), annexed to the Treaty of Amsterdam,
determines that all discussion documents and proposals of the Commission have
to be delivered to the (national) parliaments. Regional parliaments are not
mentioned in this protocol, but in practice the proposals of the Commission are
also admissible via the internet, so members of regional parliaments can easily
get them. Moreover, a period of at least six weeks is foreseen between the
introduction of a proposal and the decision of the Council, exactly to give
parliaments the time to think about it and maybe give their ministers some
instructions.
Observers have noticed that the switchover
to more polls by (qualified) majority leads to the fact that the impact of
national parliaments on European decision-making weakens[xviii].
Clear instructions can be given to a national minister, but it is possible that
he has to taste defeat during a poll. Nevertheless, the resolution that is
voted that way is also applicable in the member state where parliament was
against it. The question posed by Smith is a very important one: “[W]ho should
you charge in an instance where your own minister, in a case submitted to
decisions by qualified majorities, actually voted against a controversial
decision by which you are bound anyhow?” (Smith 1996: 15). Before we argued
that from a democratic point of view it is justifiable, even desirable that
majority ballots occur. The democratic deficit that threatens to arise that way
can only be filled by giving the European Parliament the power of co-decision.
For most areas that fall under the qualified majority ballot, this already is
the case.
But another problem arises. Many
parliaments are looking for ways to enforce their grip on the activities of
their ministers in the Council and think about refining the system of the
‘instructed minister’ and especially enforce it: parliament has to exert more
supervision on how a minister behaves[xix].
Suppose that in every member state parliaments gave their ministers precise
instructions. If the ministers want to exceed their mandate, they first have to
give feedback to their parliament or they can be sanctioned by the home base.
Obviously this would make the meetings more rigorous, looking for compromises
will be more difficult and it would slow down the process. Decision-making,
especially in the EU, where visions of various cultures and interests have to
be reconciled, asks for compromises. Often package
deals are necessary to overcome the deadlock and make headway. For this
form of decision-making confidential meetings are required, with a limited
number of participants who dispose of a relatively ample mandate (Sejersted
1996: 126; Smith 1996: 15). If fifteen or more parliaments mingled in the
concrete negotiations and strictly defined the negotiation margins of the
ministers and the members of the working groups, the dynamic of the
negotiations would suffer from this. It would for example be crazy to formulate
in an open parliamentary debate a relapse position; this would seriously weaken
the negotiation position of the minister and the parliamentary influence would
have the contrary effect (see Gustavsson 1996: 116). Kassim, Peters and Wright
point out another element: “Even if there are not partisan differences over
policy there may be sufficient institutional jealousy to create difficulties if
the parliament is an active player in the co-ordination exercise.” (Kassim,
Peters, Wright 2000: 17). Put differently, there is a risk that parliaments
will feel obliged to make it clear once in a while that they can block a
measure. If each parliament does it in turns, there is danger of a deadlock in
numerous dossiers. The conclusion of Hilf and Burmeister is probably correct:
“Any voting on EC
secondary legislation by national parliaments would not lead to ‘more’
democracy but to a rather inefficient, if not chaotic, situation and thus
finally to a demise in democratic legitimacy” (Hilf, Burmeister 1996: 74)
The idea of giving national ministers of
parliaments an exact and well-defined mandate, seems very tempting and is easy
to implement (treaty modifications are not required for this), but it has a
perverse effect. At first sight this measure seems very sound from a democratic
point of view, but doing this would endanger the integration dynamics.
Does this mean that parliaments should have
no role to play and that all debates have to occur in an atmosphere of secrecy?
Absolutely not. To guarantee legitimacy of the decisions, a democratic control
is required and directly elected persons should be able to have a substantial
involvement in the decision-making process. As was suggested earlier, the
European Parliament has an important role to play in this. In many policy
areas, this Parliament is already quite powerful and recent research shows that
the points of view of the Parliament are taken seriously: many by the
Parliament voted amendments survived the decision-making procedure and can be
found in the final texts of law, often against the original point of view of
the Council. Michael Shackleton, a top civil servant in Parliament and a
prominent observer, says the following: “legislation is not simply a product of
agreement in the Council […] the EP can alter policy outcomes in significant
ways.” (Shackleton 2002: 107). That does not alter the fact that there still
are numerous areas (among others the second and third pillar) where the
European Parliament has little influence, while national and regional parliaments
neither have much to say. Here we can speak of a real democratic deficit.
And what about these national and regional
parliaments? Do they have to stand by and watch when it comes to European
decision-making? Absolutely not. It is not because it is not realistic to
mingle in the concrete negotiation process by taking away every room for
manoeuvre from the national ministers that parliaments have to turn away from
Brussels. Parliamentary debates about various measures that are under
discussion, can without a doubt embellish the vision of a minister and
influence his/her point of view. The debate can contribute to the fact that the
minister gets a clear view on national and regional importance and parliaments
can give their ministers a clear direction or even recommendations, which could
impossibly be ignored completely (Hilf, Burmeister 1996: 74). From that point
of view it could be useful to let (both regional and national) members of
parliament participate in the co-ordination committees where the 'national
standpoint' is being formulated. But this is something totally different than
giving a minister a specific and well-defined mandate that can absolutely not
be exceeded. If a final decision seriously deviates from the position
parliament has taken, a minister can later be asked to give an explanation.
Then a minister could justify why he/she had to accept a compromised point of
view to prevent the realisation of a final text that was even further away from
desiderata of parliament. If decision-making processes are followed closely by
national and regional parliaments, they will be confronted with the points of
view of other member states and interest groups, what allows them to situate
the end result in a better way.
Good contacts and a smooth interaction
between on the one hand national and regional parliaments and on the other hand
the European Parliament (informal or formalised in committees) can contribute
to a better defence of specific national and regional interests. Concrete
problems or concerns can be brought under the attention of members of the
European Parliament from for example the same electoral district or the same
political family. That can translate itself in proposals for amendments from
the European Parliament.
But it is not only because of the direct
promotion of interests that it is useful for national or regional parliaments
to go deeply into the pending European measures. After all, the directives or
regulations that are being made nowadays contain elements that have to be
transferred into national or regional rules in a couple of months or years. Or
they form the framework in which the following years national and regional
transport and environmental and development policies etc. will be pursued. It
is not an unnecessary luxury to keep an eye on negotiations and to analyse
proposals. Keeping informed about what is going on is a minimum option.
Some authors notice that the monitoring of
European measures brings along practical problems. Norton says it this way
“[t]he existing workload of some parliaments means that it will be difficult
for them to be more involved in EU affairs.” (Norton 1996: 32; also Kassim
2000a: 44; Pedersen 2000: 232-233). In fact this is not correct, because sooner
or later parliaments will be confronted with European rules. Of course it is
important that parliament disposes of (among others personal) support, but this
is a matter of internal organisation for the parliaments themselves[xx].
One can wonder whether it is useful to pursue or prepare debates about European
measures in the ‘Standing Committee for European Affairs’ of parliament[xxi].
It is absolutely logical that in the various councils of ministers various
specialised ministers are seated (not always the minister of Foreign Affairs),
and so it should be that the 'functional' or ‘technical’ committees of the
parliaments, each for their own policy area, follow all relevant European
initiatives from an early stage. For defining a national or regional interest
the various specialised committees dispose of a lot of expertise and moreover
will be confronted most directly with European rules when executing their
activities. Also Sejersted sees it like this:
“In order to
influence European policy a parliament must integrate it into everyday
parliamentary life, and look upon it as an extension of national policy, not as
an extraneous matter to be treated separately and with care.” (Sejersted 1996: 156)
European politics do not have to be
snuggled away; it is a matter for all the members of parliament.
And finally some thoughts about
subsidiarity. This is an instrument to determine when the EU has to act in a
legislative way. Subsidiarity means that what a smaller unit can do in an
adequate way does not have to be done by a larger unit, unless it performs
better[xxii].
In a Protocol (no. 30) annexed to the Treaty of Amsterdam, it is said that the
Commission has to justify its legislative proposals in the light of
subsidiarity. The Council and the European Parliament have to investigate this
and take into account the subsidiarity principle throughout the decision-making
procedure. In other words, self-discipline of the European institutions is very
important. Sometimes it is argued that this cannot be sufficient and an extra
'test' is necessary. Some national and regional parliaments insist on this.
Control on the execution of the subsidiarity principle can be political or
judicial. Political control is exercised by the European institutions
themselves. National parliaments are only involved in this partially (through
their minister in the Council). Within the framework of the convention debates
various scenarios were formulated to extend political control (the foundation
of an ad hoc inspection body, the entry of a representative of the parliaments
in the national delegations of the Council etc.). Above we have already
mentioned it more than once that – not at the least from a democratic point of
view – it would not be very wise to make the decision-making process more
difficult. In September 02, the working group on subsidiarity reached broad
agreement on setting up an ‘early warning system’ of a political nature,
intended to reinforce the monitoring of compliance with the principle of
subsidiarity by national parliaments, without complicating or lengthening the
legislative process too much. In the ‘Draft Protocol on the application of the
principles of subsidiarity and proportionality’ (CONV 579/03) the Praesidium of
the Convention proposes that if national parliaments think the principle of
subsidiarity is being breached, they can sound the alarm. Where at least one
third of national parliaments issue reasoned opinions on the Commission
proposal’s non-compliance with the principle of subsidiarity, the Commission
shall review its proposal. After such review, the Commission may decide to
maintain, amend or withdraw its proposal. The Commission shall give reasons for
its decision (CONV 579/03, Annex 1).
Judicial control on subsidiarity on
European level is practised nowadays by the Court of Justice (the creation of a
separate 'subsidiarity chamber' that would specialise on testing legislative
proposals to a number of criteria can be considered). But at the moment an
appeal for annulment because of violation of the subsidiarity principle can
only be started by directly and individually involved persons, member states,
the Council, the Commission or the European Parliament. National parliaments
cannot directly commence a proceeding. Neither can regions (and their
parliaments). An entrance for parliaments to the Court of Justice to defend the
principle of subsidiarity would be defensible, but the fear could arise that
more or less every legislative proposal of the Commission is brought for
judging to the Court by a parliament. If one wants to prevent this, one could
introduce a barrier, so the subsidiarity test can only be applied for if a
significant number of parliaments or members of parliament want it. This should
also improve co-operation between the various parliaments. In the
aforementioned Draft Protocol the Praesidium of the Convention states that the
Court of Justice shall have jurisdiction to hear actions brought by Member
States on grounds of infringement of the principle of subsidiarity, where
appropriate at the request of their parliaments (CONV 579/03, Annex 1). A direct
access for the parliaments to the Court of Justice is not proposed. The
question of application and control on the subsidiarity principle stays very
complex. It would lead us too far to go into it further.
Practice shows that once the
decision-making process formally starts, namely when a proposal for a
regulation, directive or other legislative measure is introduced to the Council
(and to the European Parliament), there is little space left for fundamental
changes. Above it was said that national and regional parliaments have an
interest in following the current decision-making in a decent way. If these
parliaments only concentrate on
pending legislative proposals, then they are overtaken by the events.
The brainstorming
phase is very important in European decision-making. Especially what
concerns activities in the framework of the first pillar, the Commission tries
to get a more exact picture in this phase of what lives in the member states
and among other people involved. It is wasted effort for the Commission if
means are invested in drawing up a legislative measure many member states and
powerful interest groups are against (Decock 2001: 13). So around certain
policy topics the Commission creates temporary or lasting, formal or informal
networks. Previously we have talked about this. Functionally organised
interests are involved in this and the Commission will regularly (through the
Permanent Representation) ask the member states to delegate experts to
preparatory meetings.
Because of the informal character of these
processes it is not easy for parliaments to stay informed about what 'is going
to happen'. Of course it helps if a parliament has good contacts with interest
groups and especially if it is informed by ‘its’ government when this
government is invited by the services of the Commission for consultations. Some
things are even predictable. What concerns the first pillar, a relatively
detailed assessment can be made of the expected Commission initiatives on the
basis of (1) the yearly programme of work of the Commission, (2) green papers,
white papers and long-term action programmes in the policy areas concerned
(e.g. the Environment Action Programme), (3) statements of the Commission in
which new plans are announced, (4) requests of the Council of Ministers, the
European Council or the European Parliament to launch a proposal in a certain
area, (5) agreements on multilateral fora (e.g. in the framework of the
Convention on Climate Change or the discussions in the World Trade
Organisation). Sometimes the existing regulations contain an 'expiration date'
or a date is foreseen on which the rule has to be actualised. Moreover, in
December 2003 a long-term strategic program for the next three years will be
drawn up for the first time. The yearly programme of work of the Council will
be deducted from it[xxiii].
On the basis of this information and what is called fingerspitzengefühl for European politics it is thus possible to
estimate quite precisely what topics will be discussed on the preparatory
level.
So it is not only useful to organise
parliamentary debates about European measures that can already be found in an
advanced stadium of decision-making (as we said before), but it is also useful
to study European green and white papers, the programme of work of the
Commission etc. in the relevant functional or technical standing committees of
national and regional parliaments. A parliament can deduct from this which
decisions are planned on medium term and can think about the consequences. If a
parliament judges it can add a specific point of view to the discussion, there
is no reason not to do it: it can occur by means of a ‘written statement’, a
national or regional expert or agreements with members of the European
Parliament that – since a generalisation of the co-decision procedure – are
involved more and more in the prelegislative process. If all kinds of lobbies
can make clear their points of view, it is absolutely legitimate a parliament
does the same by making clear a point supported by a majority in this
parliament. The prelegislative phase does not have to be the private hunting
ground of experts and functional interest groups. Some authors say it very
explicitly:
“It has […] been
argued that national parliaments should re-think their way of operating, and
start to act more as lobbyists, especially before the Commission […]” (Sejersted 1996: 148)
Or:
“It will become more and
more important to see, to what extent candidates for membership of the
parliaments […] are able to participate in the European communication and
networking systems, to pass the will of the people over to the European level.”
(Pernice
2001: 17)
But there is a more fundamental reason why
parliamentary systems should try to follow the prelegislative process. In spite
of efforts of the Commission to get a correct image of what lives in the Union,
it is known that certain interests succeed better in letting their voice be
heard on EU level than others.
“As is known from
long experience at the national level, representation of interests through
pluralist networks does not treat all interests and citizens equally; instead
it privileges the well funded over the poorly funded, and it privileges
interests that are organised for other reasons over those that must form organisations
primarily for the purpose of influencing policy. Thus it intends to privilege
business over labour, and both business and labour over consumers.
Intermediation by interest groups tends to “disaggregate the citizen,”
emphasizing only certain varieties of needs.” (Katz, Wessels 1999: 244-245)
Do parliaments – as representatives of the
people of a certain state or region – not have the duty to make sure that all
interest groups are dealt with, also the less organised[xxiv]?
Here a parliamentary contribution can be a huge surplus-value – it can give the
Commission a better view on what lives in the Union and what it learns from the
strongly organised interest groups and experts. In that case parliaments can
have a warning function.
But more in general parliaments can also
inspire the policy from the bottom of the ladder: starting from regional or
national problems and finding out how Europe can deal with them. From regional
or national debates, a European agenda setting can be made. Participation in the
prelegislative process can only occur when parliaments succeed in anticipating
the formal decision-making process. To do this, parliaments have to keep an
overview on what is about to happen in the legislative field. This requires a
thorough insight of the members of parliament and their staff in the less
formal (but not less crucial) side of the European decision-making process and
the preparedness to participate in this (what is not really a traditional
parliamentary activity). But it is a unique and relatively effective
possibility to influence decision-making:
“If in Community
affairs it has become more precarious to mandate or influence national
ministers, then the lesson for national parliaments is surely that they will
have to try harder to influence the Commission or the European Parliament at
earlier stages.” (Munro
1996: 95)
At first sight this sounds boring and
contrary to the 'logic of a member of parliament'. Members of parliament should
especially ‘score’ and thorough work in the standing committees rarely is the
cause of the fact that they have to be in
the picture. Members of parliaments are invited more easily for television
debates because they want to give away free garbage bags, because they demand
the resignation of a minister or because they think Tom and Jerry incite violence (as was recently brought up by a
Belgian Member of Parliament). The monitoring of European measures is at first
sight not a sexy activity. For most
members of parliaments it is only useful to undergo further training into this
if the media pays attention to European measures and if a broad debate is held
about it. However, they can try to fill the bridging function themselves,
exactly by making it clear that political choices lie hidden behind technical
dossiers and that the impact on the daily lives of the average European is very
deep.
Finally we will discuss in short the role
of the parliaments when the execution of European decisions is concerned. What
concerns the binding power of European 'legislation', the case is described
relatively clear in the treaties: regulations are binding in their entirety and
directly applicable in every member state, while directives are binding with
regard to the result that has to be reached but national authorities are
responsible for the choice of form and methods (art. 249 EU). The
implementation of European rules in national and regional (and sometimes even
local) rules is arranged differently in various member states. Some authors see
a tendency in which implementation is passed on more often to governments
(Sejersted 1996: 154). Nevertheless, concerning directives there still is a
(sometimes wide) margin, in which various policy options can be taken to reach
the desired result. More and more people are saying that in the future one will
work more with framework legislation and it seems perfectly logical that
parliaments decide about the exact implementation in a specific state or
region.
Both national and regional parliaments have
an important responsibility concerning the execution of European decisions. The
success and surplus value of European integration depend on the respect that is
shown in the member states and their regions towards the rules of the game of
the integration process. A correct and timely implementation of European rules
is one of those rules. It is important that this is a permanent point of
interest in parliamentary activities; there is no excuse for an incomplete or
late implementation.
There are also rules that are determined by
the Council (together with the European Parliament or not), but have to be
further executed by European institutions. Normally this is the task of the
Commission, but the Council can lay down conditions and directly execute
certain executive powers itself (art. 202, 211 EC). In real terms, this often
leads to the fact that the Commission is assisted (or carefully watched) in its
executive powers by various committees, in which representatives (normally on
the expert level) of the member states are seated. Think for example about the
veterinary committee where one decided about measures to limit the spread of
the mad cow disease. Here we speak about comitology. The exact role and power
of these committees can differ enormously[xxv].
Although one sees to it that the various member states are represented in the
committees, it is striking that parliaments do not have anything to do with it.
The comitology process escapes many parliaments completely[xxvi].
In general transparency of this system is very limited (Newman 2001: 370-371).
Above all, we have to wonder whether it is useful to leave the execution of
decisions not entirely to the Commission. Sometimes necessary decisions are put
aside or executed in a bad way because in a certain committee there was no agreement.
If parliaments increased their grip on 'their' experts, this would influence
the preparedness to compromise in an even more negative way, so important
executive decisions cannot be decided upon. If during the execution choices
have to be made that go beyond technical nature and where committees are
considered useful, democratic control of the European Parliament is probably
more appropriate (see Shackleton 2002: 108-109).
Parliaments find that their legislative
freedom is seriously restricted and that it is not easy to control the European
activities of the ministers. This only really became noticeable in the mid
eighties, when the European Community started completing the internal market.
As a result, national parliaments began establishing specialised standing
committees in order to follow up European politics. Meanwhile, various regional
parliaments have followed this example. Of course, there are considerable
differences between member states and regions, but in general it should be
noted that parliaments hardly influence the realisation of European rules. This
often leads to frustrations. Today there are several member states that want
institutional reformations, reserving a stronger role for the parliaments.
On the other hand, research showed that
many members of parliament in the member states do not really have an elaborate
opinion about Europe. Richard Katz, a political scientist who is attached to
the John Hopkins University, speaks about the ‘non-attitude’ towards European
political themes (Katz 1999: 40). In many parliaments, European themes are
papered over in one specialised committee and only few members of parliament
seem to be interested in following up this committee. In the best case, a
plenary debate will now and then be organised about almost existential
questions with regard to Europe’s future.
However, the daily European politics in several policy areas is hardly
the subject of a more elaborate debate. This is incomprehensible, especially
because all members of parliament, while exercising their job, are permanently
confronted with the European directives or regulations that form the margins in
which they can act legislatively. Furthermore, it is remarkable that European
politics, also in the national media, hardly gets its position, while every day
more important and consequential decisions are made (with a concrete impact on
the life of the average European) around the Schumanplein than in an average parliament. What exactly causes
this disinterest among the media and politicians is difficult to find out and
it is not the subject of this contribution.
We have already stated repeatedly that
parliaments can play an important European role. They do not need to become
frills, such as for example the royal families, who are still there for the
symbolics, but in general have no real power. However, this does not mean that
parliaments should be capable of blocking every European measure, because
therefore the need for a powerful European policy is too great. In this contribution,
we have emphasised that current problems often have an international dimension
or that they are by-products of economic, cultural and technological
globalisation processes. Neither national states, nor regions are capable of
regulating these processes. An isolated policy is just not enough. Only a vigorous European attitude can offer
answers. However, decision-making cannot be ‘cut off’ of what is going on in
the member states and regions. In the ‘formal’ part of decision-making,
ministers play an important role, whether or not with the European Parliament.
In their pursuit of more democracy in the EU this European Parliament is an
objective ally of national and regional parliaments. We have proved that the
different parliaments ultimately are very complementary and that each almost
has its own territory.
However, crucial steps in the
decision-making process escape a direct democratic control. This has also to do with the fact that most
measures are very technical and that various interests should be reconciled if
possible. This leads to a decision-making process whereby networks play a large
role and defence of interests highly occurs on functional basis (instead of on
territorial basis). As a result, there is a certain tension: the decision-making
passes off relatively efficiently, but sometimes there is a lack of legitimacy.
There is at least the perception of a democratic deficit. It is not a law of Medes and Persians that
this should be filled up by parliaments.
Nevertheless, we have argued that parliaments can be crucial links in
the legitimacy of the European project: they still have responsibilities for
inspiring, influencing, orientating the policy.
We have already described that parliaments
in different phases of the decision-making process (could) have a specific
contribution in various ways. The
‘European role’ regional and national parliaments (could) play, includes a lot
more than the defence of some specific national or regional interests and than
the correct implementation of what was decided on. Parliaments have a better
position than many other participants in the decision-making process in order
to keep an eye on the broad outlines of different measures. They can reflect on
the consequences of policy choices in long term. They can reflect on the political and sometimes ideological
choices which are included in the draft decisions (such as the migration
problem or the tension between ecology and economy), and which are not always
reflected on by experts and lobbies. They can fulfil a warning function if it
seems that certain less organised interests do not succeed in getting through
the networks and as such are systematically threatened to be ignored. Furthermore, they can set the agenda by,
basing themselves on their knowledge and analysis of regional and national
problems, urging the EU to take action.
If parliaments succeed in contributing all
this in the debate during the decision-making procedure, they prove their
surplus value. The involvement of parliaments can enrich the European output
qualitatively. The question is especially which preconditions should be
satisfied so that parliaments can also effectively realise this surplus value.
Often the lack of institutional reformations is stressed. The Laeken
Declaration explicitly put forward this theme and as part of the Convention, a
separate working group was established, which should look into the position of
national parliaments. It is a pity that, in this context, one only speaks about
national parliaments and as such forgets
about regional parliaments. As
already said, regional parliaments are confronted with exactly the same
experiences and also their contributions to the European decision-making can be
a surplus value. The conditions that are nowadays applicable to national
parliaments (cf. Protocol no. 9 of the Declaration of Amsterdam) could also be
perfectly applicable to most regional parliaments.
Within the framework of current Convention
debates, many different proposals are launched in order to enforce the grip of
parliaments on European decision-making.
The ‘Draft Protocol on the role of national parliaments in the European
Union’ (currently under discussion by the Convention) proposes measures
(related to access to information) to be taken by the Union’s institutions in
order to facilitate scrutiny by the parliaments (CONV 579/03, Annex III).
Co-operation between parliaments is encouraged. In this article, we have also
stated that some involvement of the (regional and national) parliaments in the
application and control on the subsidiarity principle, could seem justified.
Also the embedding of the convention methodology (for treaties revisions and
history-making decisions) can be considered. Numerous other proposals even go
further. In that way some members of the Convention have been pushing for a
‘red card’ role for parliaments: e.g. if more than two third of parliaments
raise the alarm then the Commission should withdraw its legislative proposal.
Other members of the Convention plead for the introduction of a (whether or not
merely advisory) second chamber at the European Parliament, a kind of senate
composed of representatives of the parliaments. There are many versions of the
proposal for two chambers (for example that they should be involved only in
those policy areas for which the European Parliament has no co-decision power).
Many of the suggested ideas are not new (Dubouis 1996: 60-63; Pernice 2001:
12-14). Nevertheless, although the suggestions to give the parliaments an
additional say in the formal structure of decision-making seem to be
attractive, we have to pay attention not to complicate the European
decision-making procedures too much, not to make them less transparent. After
all, it is not useful that every measure – before being applicable – finds a
parliamentary majority in each of the (now fifteen, later at least twenty-five)
member states and their regions. At first sight, this would be very democratic
(member states or regions shall not be confronted any more with European rules,
which they do not support), but this would end the European integration
process. The Union would not be able any more to take these vigorous decisions,
which are necessary to handle the international problems or to lead the
globalisation in the good direction. If a member state or region subscribes the
objectives of the EU, because of its membership in the EU and if it had a
contribution in the formulation of these objectives (i.e. the basic treaty),
then a member state or region should also understand that some decisions will
be accepted less enthusiastically. Democracy does not mean that one is always
right and that all decisions become vague compromises that cannot be opposed
to, because they have little substance anymore. Democracy also implies that
sometimes you do not get precisely what you want. This does not mean that regional and national parliaments should
not be involved in the decision-making. On the contrary, this would lead to
alienation, which is very counterproductive. Moreover, as already stated, a
parliamentary contribution can be a surplus value. One should find the balance
between efficiency and participation in decision-making. The idea to accept a
member of parliament in the delegations attending the Council can be, for
example, interesting. The Convention has to put forward creative suggestions.
In this article, we have stated that some
institutional reformations would be very useful, but that there is especially
an important responsibility for the parliaments themselves. The realisation of
their potential surplus value is also dependent on the internal organisation
and on the way they handle European politics (see also Wessels, Katz 1999: 11,
Norris 1999: 86). Even without important institutional modifications
parliaments can considerably increase their influence on the European
decision-making. And with this, we do not refer to the possibility of
parliaments to hold on ‘their’ ministers in the Council by giving them a strict
mandate that cannot be ignored unsanctioned. Using this weapon systematically
would be a rather frenetic reflex, of which we have already described the
disadvantages. There are still other ways to participate in the incredible
dazzling and dynamic process of European decision-making. Parliaments can be
involved in the realisation of the (national) point of view which will be
defended in the Council, contacts can be made with the European Parliament
(whether or not formalised), members of parliament can become part of or make
contacts with the networks where the European legislation is being prepared,
parliaments can sometimes take up a position together etc.
However, the ultimate condition remains
that parliaments should be prepared to integrate the European politics in their
daily activities and to communicate this to the people. But if a draft decision
is only discussed when it is in a final phase, this will lead to frustration
because at that moment it becomes difficult to introduce modifications.
Therefore it is important that parliaments especially work proactive and,
proceeding from their specialised standing committees, follow and judge the
developments in the different policy areas. Parliaments can become strong
players in the concrete decision-making processes with well-founded arguments
and they can certainly influence the ‘negotiation sphere’. By means of
permanent attention for European developments in different policy areas,
parliaments are prevented from being taken by surprise at the moment that
European legislation has to be implemented.
For national and regional parliaments this
means a whole new challenge: it is about a new domain of interest, about other
tasks and new techniques and work methods should be handled in order to
‘silver’ their potential surplus value. Possibly this is not easy. In this
contribution, we have made some suggestions and academics can draw up many
strategies about how European politics can be integrated in the activities, but
eventually an exchange of experience will be most useful. Perhaps it is
especially in this point of view that forums such as COSAC (for national
parliaments, cf Rideau 1996; Cygan 2001: 37-48; Millar 1996: 2-3) and CALRE
(for regional parliaments) are useful.
Moreover, national and regional parliaments can learn a lot from each other
because they are confronted with exactly the same challenges.
In this article, we have argued that it is
too early to proclaim the ‘decline of parliamentary democracy’ (Andersen, Burns
1996). European integration, however, has changed political reality in the
member states enormously. Parliaments,
both regional and national, do have a European role in this new context. It is not simple to take it up, but there is
no alternative. A parliament that
ignores this role is made redundant.
Andersen, S., Burns, T. (1996) ‘The European Union and the erosion of
parliamentary democracy: a study of post-parliamentary governance’, in:
Andersen, S., Eliassen, K. (eds.) The
European Union: how democratic is it?, London: Sage, 227-251.
Andersen, S., Eliassen, K. ( 1996) ‘Introduction: dilemmas,
contradictions and the future of European democracy’, in: Andersen, S.,
Eliassen, K. (eds.) The European Union:
how democratic is it?, London: Sage, 1-11.
Boucké, T., Vos, H. (2001) Constitutional
regions in the European Union – an examination of their added value, of
critical success factors and political consequences, Brussel: Ministerie
van de Vlaamse Gemeenschap.
Bradley, K. (2002) ‘The European Court of Justice’, in: Peterson, J.,
Shackleton, M. (eds.) The institutions of
the European Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 118-138.
Cygan, A. (2001) National
parliaments in an integrated Europe – an Anglo-German perspective, The
Hague: Kluwer.
Decock, J. (2001) Besluitvorming in de Europese Unie – casus
milieubeleid, Gent: Vakgroep Politieke Wetenschappen.
Dewachter, W. (1997)
‘Parlement en regering: symbool en macht’, in: Maes, R. (ed.) Democratie – legitimiteit – nieuwe politieke
cultuur, Leuven: Acco, 25-42.
Dubouis, L. (1996) ‘The European Union: an opportunity for the French
parliament to recover powers?’, in: Smith, E. (ed.) National parliaments as cornerstones of European integration, The
Hague: Kluwer, 49-63.
Greenwood (1997), Representing
interests in the European Union, Hampshire: Macmillan.
Gustavsson (1996) ‘Preserve or abolish the democratic deficit?’, in:
Smith, E. (ed.) National parliaments as
cornerstones of European integration, The Hague: Kluwer, 100-123.
Haibach, G. (1999) ‘Council decision 1999/468 – a new comitology
decision for the 21st century!?’, in: Eipascope, 3, 10-18.
Hilf, M., Burmeister, F. (1996) ‘The German parliament and European
integration’, in: Smith, E. (ed.) National
parliaments as cornerstones of European integration, The Hague: Kluwer,
64-79.
Jeffery, C. (2002) ‘Social and regional interests: ESC and Committee of
the Regions’, in: Peterson, J., Shackleton, M. (eds.) The institutions of the European Union, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 326-346.
Kassim, H. (2000a) ‘The United Kingdom’, in:
Kassim, H., Peters, B.G., Wright, V. (eds.), The national co-ordination of EU policy: the domestic level,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 22-53.
Kassim, H. (2000b) ‘Conclusion: the national
co-ordination of EU Policy: confronting the challenge’, in: Kassim, H., Peters,
B.G., Wright, V. (eds.), The national
co-ordination of EU policy: the domestic level, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 235-264.
Kassim, H., Peters, B.G., Wright, V. (2000)
‘Introduction’, in: Kassim, H., Peters, B.G., Wright, V. (eds.), The national co-ordination of EU policy: the
domestic level, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1-21.
Katz, R. (1999) ‘Representation, the locus of democratic legitimation
and the role of the national parliaments in the European Union’, in: Katz, R.,
Wessels, B. (eds.) The European
Parliament, the national parliaments, and European integration, Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 21-44.
Katz, R., Wessels, B. (1999) ‘Parliaments and democracy in Europe in the
era of the euro’, in: Katz, R., Wessels, B. (eds.) The European Parliament, the national parliaments, and European
integration, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 231-247.
Millar, D. (1996) Crisis or
opportunity? Constitutional issues: the European Parliament and national
parliaments, Discussion paper of the Jean Monnet Group of Experts.
Müller, W. (2000) ‘Austria’, in: Kassim, H., Peters, B.G., Wright, V. (eds.), The national co-ordination of EU policy: the domestic level,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 201-218.
Munro, C. (1996) ‘The UK Parliament and EU institutions – partners or
rivals?’, in: Smith, E. (ed.) National
parliaments as cornerstones of European integration, The Hague: Kluwer,
80-99.
Newman, M. (2001) ‘Democracy and accountability in the EU’, in:
Richardson, J. (ed.) European Union –
power and policy-making, London: Routledge, 357-374.
Norris, P. (1999) ‘Recruitment into the European Parliament’, in: Katz,
R., Wessels, B. (eds.) The European
Parliament, the national parliaments, and European integration, Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 86-102.
Norton, P. (1996) ‘National parliaments in Western Europe’, in: Smith,
E. (ed.) National parliaments as
cornerstones of European integration, The Hague: Kluwer, 19-35.
Österud, Ö. (1996) ‘Democracy between national government and
supranationality – a concise exposition’, in: Smith, E. (ed.) National parliaments as cornerstones of European
integration, The Hague: Kluwer, 179-186.
Pedersen, T. (2000) ‘Denmark’, in: Kassim, H., Peters, B.G., Wright, V. (eds.), The national co-ordination of EU policy: the domestic level,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 219-234.
Pernice, I. (2001) ‘The role of national parliaments in the European
Union’, in: Walter Hallstein
Institut-paper 5/01.
Peterson, J., Shackleton, M. (2002) ‘Conclusion’, in: Peterson, J.,
Shackleton, M. (eds.) The institutions of
the European Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 347-367.
Raunio, T., Hix, S. (2001) ‘Backbenchers learn to fight back: European
integration and parliamentary government’, in: Goetz, K., Hix, S. (eds.) Europeanised politics? European integration
and national political systems, London: Frank Cass, 142-168.
Rideau, J. (1996) ‘National parliaments and the European Parliament:
cooperation and conflict’, in: Smith, E. (ed.) National parliaments as cornerstones of European integration, The
Hague: Kluwer, 159-178.
Scharpf, F. (1999) Governing in
Europe: effective and democratic?, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sejersted, F. (1996) ‘The Norwegian Parliament and European integration
– reflections from medium-speed Europe’, in: Smith, E. (ed.) National parliaments as cornerstones of
European integration, The Hague: Kluwer, 124-156.
Shackleton, M. (2002) ‘The European Parliament’, in: Peterson, J.,
Shackleton, M. (eds.) The institutions of
the European Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 95-117.
Smith (1996) ‘Introduction: ‘Sovereignty’ – national and popular’, in:
Smith, E. (ed.) National parliaments as
cornerstones of European integration, The Hague: Kluwer, 3-18.
Thomassen, J., Schmitt, H. (1999) ‘Partisan structures in the European
Parliament’, in: Katz, R., Wessels, B. (eds.) The European Parliament, the national parliaments, and European
integration, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 129-148.
Verhoeven, A. (1999),
‘Burgernabijheid in de Europese Unie? Enige kanttekeningen bij het
‘democratisch tekort’’, in: Tijdschrift
voor Bestuurswetenschappen en Publiekrecht, 8, 564-570.
Vos, H. (1997), ‘De EU-regio’s na Amsterdam –
het verlanglijstje van het Comité van de Regio’s’, in: Internationale Spectator, 9, 483-487.
Vos, H. (1999a) ‘Regions in the EU-decision making: a classification
scheme’, in: Studia Diplomatica, 5-6,
19-34.
Vos, H. (1999b) ‘On-going European integration and the position of the
regions: an analysis of the process and some possible future scenarios’, in:
Fischer, M., Nijkamp, P. (eds.) Spatial
dynamics of European integration —Regional and policy issues at the turn of the
century, Berlin: Springer Verlag, 179-196.
Vos, H., Baillieul, E. (2002) The
Belgian Presidency and the Post-Nice Process after Laken, Bonn: Zentrum für
Europäische Integrationsforschung.
Vos, H., Boucké, T., Devos, C. (2002) ‘The conditio sine qua non of the
added value of regions in the EU – upper-level representation as the
fundamental precondition’, in: Journal of
European Integration.
Wessels, B. (1999a) ‘European parliament and interest groups’, in: Katz,
R., Wessels, B. (eds.) The European
Parliament, the national parliaments, and European integration, Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 105-128.
Wessels, B. (1999b) ‘Institutional change and the future political
order’, in: Katz, R., Wessels, B. (eds.) The
European Parliament, the national parliaments, and European integration,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 213-228.
Wessels, B., Katz, R. (1999) ‘Introduction: European parliament,
national parliaments and European integration’, in: Katz, R., Wessels, B.
(eds.) The European Parliament, the
national parliaments, and European integration, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 3-18.
Wessels, B., Kielhorn, A. (1999) ‘Which competencies for which political
level?’, in: Katz, R., Wessels, B. (eds.) The
European Parliament, the national parliaments, and European integration,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 174-196.
[i] Later on we will discuss the question of what
sovereignty de facto means in a
globalised economy and in a world that is confronted with numerous international
problems.
[ii] The lion's share of European regulating action
takes place in the first pillar. The unanimity rule is still valid here for
(some parts of) agricultural and fishing policy, tax law, asylum and
immigration policy, economic and monetary union, trade and competition policy
and mostly also for striking international agreements.
[iii] Since Maastricht they get huge fines for doing this,
cf. Bradley 2002.
[iv] Protocol no. 9 is annexed to the Treaty of Amsterdam.
It concerns the role of national (sic) parliaments in the European Union. In
this protocol it is said that all discussion documents and proposals of the
commission have to be forwarded to the (national) parliaments. There is also a
co-operation between the European affairs committees of the various (national)
parliaments. This conference (COSAC: Conférence des organes spécialisés dans
les affaires communautaires) was founded in 1989 and gathers twice a year in
the member state that fills the European Presidency. It is mainly a discussion
forum, without real power and without the ambition to weigh on daily European
decision-making. The Committee on Institutional Affairs of the European
Parliament takes part in the COSAC-meetings (Rideau 1996, 169; Cygan 2001,
37-48; Dubouis 1996, 57; Millar 1996, 2-3).
[v] This Conference took place in Lisbon from 20 to 22
May 1999. See the report during the extraordinary session of 16 July 1999 in
the Belgian Chamber of Deputies (Chamber, 22/1 1999: 5).
[vi] It has to be said that the capacity of the EU to act market
correcting (the so-called 'positive integration') is definitely more restricted
than the capacity to liberalise markets (the so-called 'negative integration').
We cannot really speak of a positive European environmental policy, social
policy, macro economic employment policy and fiscal policy. The capacity of the
EU is least developed in those policy areas where national capacity to govern
effectively has decreased because of international competition. The European
integration has contributed to less freedom of acting of the member states,
without a sufficiently compensating increase of the capacity of the Union.
[vii] Eurobarometer 56 (fieldwork: October-November 2001)
mentions this: “On average, 53% of Europeans say they tend to trust the Union,
32% say they tend not to trust it and 15% lack an opinion. This is the most
positive result since the question was first asked in the autumn of 1997. At
that time, only 37% of EU citizens said they trusted the EU.” (p. 49)
[viii] It is incomprehensible that in most member states the
European election campaigns hardly deal with European topics. Very often, it is
all about national issues.
[ix] For an overview of some research data about the
contact between members of the European Parliament and lobbyists, see Wessels
1999a: 109
[x] Rainer Schmalz-Bruns talks in this case about
‘associative democracy’, as an alternative for parliamentary democracy
(Wessels, Katz 1999: 13).
[xi] We should not look at this too lightly and we
have to assume that economic strong groups (for example the employers) always
form a homogeneous group – sometimes the opinions within this group are very
different. (Wessels 1999a: 109-111, 115-116).
[xii] Within the framework of the convention debates
various proposals circulate, of which most have little or nothing to do with
the reinforcement of the role of regional and national parliaments (for example
the pleas for direct election of the chairman of the commission, for more
transparency in the Council, for a simplification of instruments and procedures
etc.) We do not go further into this.
[xiii] This is also the task of the Commission.
[xiv] It is paradoxical that member states, which denounce
the lack of democracy in the EU the most, often are the ones that do not really
want a reinforcement of power of the European Parliament.
[xv] Art. 191 EU says that political parties play an
important role in the integration within the EU: "They contribute to
forming a European awareness and to expressing the political will of the
citizens of the Union." But until now, there are no real European parties;
regional and national parties are a part of rather loosely structured political
families on European level.
[xvi] See Verhoeven 1999: 569.
[xvii] See the internal regulations of the Council. It was
decided by the European Council in Seville (21 and 22 June 2002) that some
debates of the Council would be public, if the Council acts according to the
co-decision procedure: the first discussion about the initiative of the
Commission and the voting – see: Conclusions of Seville (21 and 22 June 2002),
annex 2.
[xviii] See a.o. Rideau 1996: 167
[xix] Research by Katz in national parliaments shows that
national members of parliament do answer ‘too little’ in great numbers to the
question 'Does the national parliament exert too much or too little supervision
on the position the government of your country takes in the Council? (Katz
1999: 40-41) (the average on a 7-point scale in 10 countries was 5,22).
Research among a large number of national (1392) and EU members of parliament
(310) shows that a majority is in favour of the system of ‘instructed
ministers’.
[xx] Sejersted studied the Norwegian Parliament and
concludes that there are few parliamentary assistants that keep themselves busy
with research concerning European affairs. (Sejersted 1996: 143)
[xxi] See a.o. Gustavsson 1996.
[xxii] See the note of Inigo Mendes de Vigo to the
members of the Convention concerning the mandate of the working group on the
subsidiarity principle (CONV 71/02 2002: 2).
[xxiii] See the decision of the European Council of Seville
(21 and 22 June 2002), annex II, C.
[xxiv] This is probably not easy for parliaments (often
thinking in terms of minority/majority), because members of parliament
themselves are more or less associated with specific interests (Wessels 1999a:
121). More specifically for regional parliaments it is also important that they
can exert a certain control on points of view that are taken by the regional
information office (their lobby group in Brussels) that is financially
supported by public means from the region.
[xxv] For a brief introduction see a.o. Haibach 1999.
[xxvi] The Committee that deals with European affairs in the
Danish parliament does try to exert influence on the points of view the Danish
experts take in comitology. See a.o. Kassim 2000: 245; Pedersen 2000: 231.